Previous PageTable Of Contents

Paper No. 6
Measures to enhance agricultural development, trade and food security in the context of the WTO negotiations

I. Introduction

The rules and disciplines of the Agreement on Agriculture are intended to restrict the use by countries of policy measures that distort world agricultural markets. Nevertheless, there is still flexibility to use a wide range of policy options to pursue national agricultural policy objectives. For each country, the precise extent of this flexibility is determined by its specific commitments on market access, domestic support and export subsidies. With the next round of negotiations about to begin, concern has been expressed by many developing countries that their policy options for the future may be limited by the general provisions of the Agreement as well as by their specific commitments. These concerns, which are related to the issues at stake in the forthcoming negotiations, were reviewed in Paper No. 4. This paper continues that debate and identifies measures that developing countries may pursue in the forthcoming negotiations in order to preserve sufficient flexibility to achieve their agricultural production, trade and food security goals.1

I. Domestic agricultural production

In the context of the Agreement on Agriculture, a country has basically two broad policy options to support domestic production and agricultural development: border measures, i.e. through tariffs, as long as they remain within the tariff bindings; and domestic support measures, i.e. price and non-price support to farmers, again within the limits of WTO rules and commitments.

As regards border measures, in general, bound tariffs of the developing countries on agricultural products are at a level sufficiently high to allow them considerable flexibility in stabilising domestic markets or protecting producers2. However, there are some problem areas. For example, very few developing countries rationalised their bound tariffs and as a result a number of anomalies have been noted in their commitments3. For many net food-importing developing countries with large numbers of low-income households, raising tariffs has also limitations for socio-political reasons4.

As regards domestic support, the Agreement distinguishes several categories of measures: "amber" box measures (both product and non-product- specific), "green" and "blue" box measures, and (for developing countries) a special category of agricultural development measures. Of these, quantitative limits have been set only for amber box measures (through the AMS) - the exact amount depending upon each country's reported base-period (1986-88) AMS. Many developing countries reported a zero level base-period AMS. Regarding other measures, no limits on outlays have been placed; but there is a lack of clarity in the definition of these measures. As with bound tariffs, the extent of flexibility in the support of agriculture therefore depends upon what has been committed in the UR.

Besides the current WTO Members, flexibility for domestic support is needed also by developing countries negotiating their accession to WTO, particularly taking into account their developmental and food security concerns.

On both of these broad policy options, developing countries may need to pursue a two-pronged strategy. The first would be to remove some of the imbalances in existing provisions in the Agreement on Agriculture that have allowed considerable production and trade-distorting support by countries that can afford it. In this respect, the following reforms may be considered:

The second component of the strategy would be to ensure that the developing countries have the necessary degree of flexibility to pursue agricultural development and food security policies. This may require clarifications/interpretations/adjustments to the current provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture, as follows:

III. Access to world markets

For a country dependent on agricultural exports, increasing agricultural export earnings is essential to economic development and food security, and particularly so for developing countries. Their combined share of agricultural exports is not only low (about 30 percent of the world total), but has also been stagnant, and many of them depend on the world market for satisfying much of their food needs. While the results of the UR have contributed to improving market access for products of export interest to developing countries, much remains to be done, including further reductions in tariff levels and tariff escalation, improved access to tariff rate quotas (TRQs), and curtailment of the use of safeguards and new non-tariff measures. Some reforms to be considered include the following:

IV. Domestic market stability

The reforms outlined above should provide considerable room for increasing domestic food production. Improved market access and other related reforms should contribute to raising export earnings, which are fundamental for improving the capacity to import food, particularly by LDCs and NFIDCs.

Although these reforms can be expected to contribute somewhat to the stability of global agricultural markets, these markets are by nature volatile. There are general WTO provisions for stabilising domestic markets (e.g. anti-dumping and safeguard measures), but they are not useful for many developing countries, which need more accessible and simpler instruments. Thus, the following reforms may be sought:

V. Complementary measures

The Marrakesh Decision

The Decision on Measures Concerning the Possible Negative Effects of the Reform Programme on Least Developed and Net Food-Importing Developing Countries calls for assistance to be given to these countries if they are adversely affected by the reform process. To date, there has not been any concrete benefit stemming from the Decision. Accordingly, LDCs and NFIDCs could aim to include, in a revised Decision, provisions that would make it more effective and responsive to their needs:

Capacity building

Finally, despite improvements in recent years, the participation of many developing countries in multilateral trade negotiations remains weak and their capacity to implement the various agreements and to take advantage of trade opportunities is limited. Clearly, much needs to be done in this area to level the playing field. Technical and financial assistance on capacity building is essential, some of the priority areas being as follows:



1 Many of the suggestions included in this paper were expressed by participants from developing countries in a series of regional and other seminars organized by FAO in 1998 and 1999.

2 High tariffs are not unique to the developing countries - developed country tariffs on many temperate-zone products are even higher.

3 One such anomaly is that several of them committed themselves to an across-the-board tariff rate, often at relatively high rates, e.g. 100 percent. While such a commitment could be useful for some sensitive products, it has no value for many other products. Similarly, some countries bound their tariffs at such low levels that border measures offer little room for stabilisation and/or protection in years of depressed world markets.

4 Higher tariffs imply higher prices not only for domestic producers but for consumers as well. It may be argued that a possible remedy for this dilemma is to use the customs revenues generated from tariffs to target food insecure households, while allowing producers to benefit from higher domestic prices. Such an option, however, requires good administrative capacity to identify households in need (thus minimising leakage) and an institutional infrastructure to implement resource transfers to them in a cost-effective manner.

5 See document WT/MIN(96)/14, Geneva, 1997.

Top Of PageTable Of Contents