Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


VIII. Analytical Results and Discussion


This chapter summarizes and compares estimates of profit per unit output of broiler and hog production between small and large-scale farms and between independent and contract farms, first without incorporating the cost of family labor. It then proceeds to incorporate the effects of policy distortions, explicitly accounting for the cost of family labor, the capture of environmental externalities, and the impact of transaction costs on farm technical/allocative efficiency. The effect of prices, fixed factors, and technology on profit per unit are also discussed prior to the treatment of transaction costs.

The results for broiler farms and hog farms are reported separately beginning with the discussion on broiler farms.

8.1 Broiler Farms

8.1.1 Comparative Profit Performance

Profits per kilogram of output by scale, with and without contracts

Figure 8.1 shows farm profits per kilogram output across farm types. Per kilogram profits from production and sale of main output (live broilers) were highest for contract growers. Small contract growers received marginally higher profits (4.1 pesos per kg) than their larger counterparts (4.0 pesos per kg).

Large independent producers realized the lowest profits per kilogram (1.1 pesos). Small independents earned significantly higher profits per kilogram (1.6 pesos per kg) than the large independents.

Regarding smallholder contract farms, distinguishing between price and fee contracts reveals the advantage of the fee contact system over the price contract and the rest.

Figure 8.1 Profit per kilogram by scale, with and without contracts, Broiler Farms, Philippines, 2002

Total farm profit by scale, with and without contracts

Total farm profit refers to profits over the latest cycle. Over 93 percent of the sample practiced the 'all-in, all-out' scheme, with an average of four to five cycles per year, each production cycle lasting 41-42 days. Figure 8.2 shows a comparison of total farm profits per cycle.

The contrast in total farm profits is stark. Scale matters. Although profits per kilogram were also relatively high among smallholder independents, total farm profits per cycle were only five percent of those obtained by large fee contract producers, and less than a tenth of the profits earned by large independent producers. Although independent smallholder profits were close to half the profits earned by small price contract producers, they were only about one-sixth those earned by smallholders with fee contracts.

Figure 8.2 Total farm profits per cycle, by scale, with and without contract, Broiler farms, Philippines, 2002.

Small fee contract growers realized more than twice the earnings of their price contract counterparts. Large fee contract producers, on the other hand, earned more than three times more than the fee contract smallholders.

Between the two types of large producers, the fee contract growers had 60 percent higher profits than the large independents, notwithstanding a smaller average flock size and lower investments per bird. Among the large farms, larger scale did not translate to higher profit overall.

Profit per unit output and scale of operations, by size quintile

Figure 8.3 shows profit per kilogram by quintile. Profit per kilogram of output, using pooled data, revealed that households belonging to the lowest quintile, producing an average of 695 kg of output per cycle, generated the highest profit at 5.3 pesos per kg. Profits per kilogram fall progressively as scale of output increases, but ticks up in the last quintile. On a per unit output basis therefore, smallholders are not inferior in generating earning.

Figure 8.3 Profit per kilogram, by quintile, Broiler farms, Philippines, 2002

8.1.2 Accounting for Market distortions

Market distortions considered are three: the non-costing of family labor; the non-accounting of social costs generated by negative environmental externalities from by-products in the form of livestock waste (manure) and dead animals; and trade and social subsidies to large integrators and to cooperatives.

Adjustments for cost of family labor

Costing unpriced family labor is expected to reduce the economic profits of the group that uses this resource most intensively: smallholders. Figure 8.4 displays comparative profits per unit of output among broiler farms after costing family labor. Using the sample wage rates to value the family labor involved, independent smallholders' average profit per unit of output is slightly reduced, from 1.6 to 1.3 pesos per kg of output. The adjustment has negligible impact on the three other groups. While this was to be expected for the large producers, the marginal effect of costing family labor on the smallholder contract group is revealing. This arises from the fact that the small contract producers had flock sizes on average five times larger than those of the independent smallholders. Profit per unit output, however, remains lowest among large independent producers.

Figure 8.4 Profit per kilogram after costing family labor, Broiler farms, Philippines, 2002

Adjustments for cost of environmental externalities

Comparative expenditures on mitigation of environmental externalities. Expenditures on mitigation of environmental externalities consisted of the following: revenue from sales of animal manure; the value of manure spread on own fields; costs of disposing of livestock waste and dead animals; fees, environmental fines, and environmental taxes paid; and compensation paid to neighbors for pollution. Where none of the related activities to mitigate environmental externalities is done, the value of expenditures on mitigation is zero. That is to say, none of the environmental costs imposed is visibly captured by the producer in this private economic activity.

Expenditures on environmental mitigation by scale, with and without contracts. Table 8.1 presents estimates of expenditures per 100 kg of output on environmental mitigation. Dividing the sample into independents plus price contract growers on the one hand and fee contract producers on the other hand, and distinguishing them further by scale of operations, yields two significant findings in terms the amount spent by broiler producers on environmental mitigation (measured in pesos per 100 kg of live-weight output). First, contract growers spent more per unit than independents, regardless of scale. Second, small independents spent about the same amount per unit as large contractors.

The question is, if mitigation expenditures differ, what determines differential rates of environmental mitigation among broiler producers?

Table 8.1 Estimates of expenditures on environmental mitigation per 100 Kilograms of output, Broiler farms, Philippines, 2002

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<10,000)

COMMERCIAL (>10,000)

Independent

Contract

Independent

Contract

Expenditure per 100 kg output

48.3

23.5

14.9

22.2

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

Determinants of expenditure on mitigation of externalities. Tobit regressions were run on environmental mitigation expenditures by broiler raisers on household, farm, and production characteristics that were theoretically conceived to affect mitigation expenditure behavior. Table 8.2 presents the results of the pooled and regrouped regressions.

For the pooled sample the salient results were four:

To distinguish the differential behavior of expenditures on mitigation of externalities by scale of operations, the sample was divided into two groups: 'all smallholders' and 'all large farms'. Table 8.2 also presents these regression results. The salient results follow, first for smallholders, then for large farms.

For smallholders:

Table 8.2. Determinants of farm expenditure on mitigation of environmental externalities from broiler production, Philippines, 2002.

EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Pooled Sample
N=116

All Small- holders
n=70

All Large Farms
n=46

All Contract Farms
n=62

All Independents
n=54

Small Contracts
n=31

Small Independents
n=39

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Education of HH head (yrs)

ns

-0.214

ns

ns

-0.246

-0.092

-0.314

Age of HH head (yrs)

0.041

0.058

ns

ns

0.078

ns

0.066

Able to sell manure in last 2 mons. (Dummy)

2.861

4.119

0.410

0.794

4.495

1.283

5.432

Land class is Agricultural(Dummy)

-0.717

-1.202

ns

ns

-1.379

ns

-3.347

Has crop land (Dummy)

1.120

2.214

ns

ns

1.702

1.043

4.402

Within LLDA jurisdiction(Dummy)

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Wage rate (PhP per hr)

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

No. of mortalities in last cycle(birds)

ns

ns

ns

ns

-0.008

0.004

ns

Distance to nearest Residential community (Kms)

-0.154

-0.213

0.127

ns

ns

-0.119

ns

No. of DOCs loaded previous batch (birds)

ns

ns

-0.00001

ns

ns

ns

ns

FCR

2.214

2.956

ns

ns

4.140

ns

4.396

Constant

-6.487

-9.075

ns

ns

-11.540

ns

-12.240

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

For large farms:

With regard to production arrangement effects, the following results were found for independents and contract growers.

For independents:

For contract growers:

In sum, regarding environmental mitigation behavior we can deduce the following:

Trade and social subsidies to integrators and cooperatives

Differential access to credit. Access to inputs credit is one feature that differentiates the production opportunities of contract growers from those of independent producers. Integrators automatically provide contract growers their intermediate inputs of day-old chicks, feeds, and vaccines and pharmaceuticals. For independent producers, that is not the case.

As Table 8.3 shows, only 13 percent of independent smallholders could obtain feeds credit from their suppliers, compared to 22 percent of large independents. For day-old chicks, only 10 percent of small independents obtained credit, and for vaccines and pharmaceuticals the figure was only three percent. In contrast, 17 percent of large independents obtained day-old chicks and pharmaceuticals on credit.

Table 8.3 Access to credit for inputs by broiler farms, by scale and production arrangement, Broiler Production, Philippines, 2002

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<10,000)

COMMERCIAL (>10,000)

Independent

Contract

Independent

Contract

Day-old chicks

9.7

100.0

17.4

100.0

Feeds

12.9

100.0

21.7

100.0

Vaccines/Pharmaceuticals

3.2

100.0

17.4

100.0

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

Access to formal credit is likewise difficult. As shown in Table 8.4, only six percent of all farmers actually borrowed from a bank for production purposes, with the interest paid averaging 15.4 percent per annum. If the farmers really needed credit, fewer independents thought they could borrow from a bank (24-28%) as compared to contract farmers (33-41%).

Table 8.4 Access to bank credit and lowest interest rates at which farmers could borrow, Broiler farms, Philippines, 2002

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<10,000)

COMMERCIAL (>10,000)

Average

Independent

Contract

Independent

Contract

Percent of farms that actually borrowed (%)

6.5

6.5

8.7

3.2

6.0

Average interest rate paid (% p.a.)

27.6

19.8

11.0

14.0

18.4

Percent of farms who think they could borrow from the bank (%)

27.6

41.4

25.0

33.3

32.4

Perceived bank interest rate (% p.a.)

9.7

14.4

13.8

14.8

13.2

Farmer's perception of bank interest for a general loan (% p.a.)

12.1

13.7

11.0

11.6

12.2

Percent of farms who believe they can get loan at 12% p.a., or less (%)

54.8

64.5

73.9

51.6

60.3

Source: UPLB-IFPRILI Field Survey, 2002-03.

The interest rate that the producers thought a bank would charge varied by group, with the only consistent pattern being that contract growers expected higher interest rates than their independent counterparts. On average, the expected rates were between 12 percent and 13 percent per annum. The table also shows the proportion of producers who believed they could get a loan at less than 12 percent per annum. No distinct pattern arises in this distribution, except the surprising result that the lowest proportion of farmers that believed they could obtain a loan at less than 12 percent per annum was unexpectedly in the large independents group. It may be worth noting that broiler producers believed they could borrow elsewhere-from relatives and friends-at much lower rates of interest. In a certain sense, smallholders may have greater access than commercial producers to informal sources of socialized credit for production purposes.

The extremely low incidence of farmers obtaining formal credit emphasizes the importance of suppliers' credit for inputs. The willingness of suppliers to provide inputs on credit depends on the cost of supplying them, which, among others, includes the cost of actually producing the inputs (e.g., feeds).

Subsidy on feeds and day-old chicks to the contract growers. It is often asserted that the large integrators offering fee contracts obtain main feed ingredients at lower prices than the smaller feed-milling integrators or other commercial feed mills. Likewise, their costs in producing day-old chicks are said to be much lower than those incurred by other producers.

On major feed ingredients, the sheer size of the integrators allows them to gain access to corn imported under the minimum access volume (MAV) commitments of the Philippines to the WTO for the period 1995-2004. With its strong protectionist policy on corn, government MAV imports are obtained at a 35 percent in-quota tariff rate, while imports outside the quota are slapped with a 60 percent rate. Feed millers who procure corn from domestic sources face domestic prices that are at par with at least 60 percent implicit tariff protection.

The large integrators are also able to import wheat in bulk, at 10 percent tariff on feed wheat and three percent tariff on food wheat. There is no enforceable mechanism, however, preventing an integrator from transforming wheat imported as food wheat (by import declaration) into feed ingredients. Thus, large integrators have access to facilities that effectively lower the cost of producing their own mixed feeds.

As a tax incentive for locating industrial operations outside Metro-Manila, in line with the government program of developing identified regional industrial centers (RICs), firms under the Board of Investments (BOI) incentives program are entitled to enjoy the privileges of duty-free import of breeding stock and capital equipment.

The large integrators are said to pass on part of their benefits from these differential tariff privileges-on grandparent and parent stock of day-old chicks and on imported feed ingredients-to their fee contract growers, to lure them away from competing integrators. This would be reflected in higher base fees per unit output than would be the case in the absence of such privileges.

On the other side of the fence, it is asserted that the large independent commercial broiler farms, together with the smaller sized local feed-milling firms that engage in price contracts with smallholder producers, do not individually have sufficient scale to effectively take advantage of formal access to MAV imports of corn or duty-free imports of grandparent and parent stock for day-old chick production. Although large independent producers may obtain wholesale price discounts from the large integrators for day-old chicks and high-quality commercial feeds, they cannot obtain them at par with the prices internal to the integrators in their conduct of fee contract growing operations.

Feed and credit subsidy to price contract growers of feed-milling and multipurpose cooperatives. Cooperatives, by legislation, are entitled to exemption from the corporate income tax. Cooperatives are perceived as generating social good in being of assistance to small and asset-poor producers. The corporate tax is levied at a uniform 32 percent on corporate net income or before-tax profit.

Most of the price contracts with smallholders were engaged in by local feed millers with no grandparent/parent stock breeding operations. Inputs are provided on credit to contract growers at market prices, plus some mark-up. The contract growers rely on the prevailing market prices of output at harvest. The integrators deduct from total sales the value of all intermediate inputs advanced on credit. Other integrators, however, charge the grower interest on the inputs advanced at prevailing bank rates for short-term loans. The integrator and contract grower then split net income 50-50. The scheme adds trust and reputation to transactions within a market system that is otherwise similar to that of the independents.

8.1.3 Determinants of profit inefficiency in broiler production

Profit frontiers were estimated where farm profit per kilogram of output was regressed on output and input prices, fixed factors (resources), interaction of fixed factors and prices, and on two variables capturing technology (the feed conversion ratio (FCR) and the animal mortality rate). With the frontier determined, the efficiency level of each farm was established, and the effects of the variables hypothesized to affect farm efficiency were simultaneously estimated.

Effects of prices, fixed factors, and technology on profit per unit output

Pooled sample. Table 8.5 shows the results of the econometric estimation of the profit frontier and the magnitude of effects of hypothesized determinants of inefficiency for the pooled sample. The salient results are below:

Table 8.5 Profit frontier estimates in broiler production, with and without contracts, Philippines, 2002

EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Pooled

Independent and price contracts

Contract fee

Small- holders

Large/Commercial

Constant

-4.535

21.896

4.790

-5.125

-31.514

Broiler price

5.551

4.849

-

4.57

8.616

DOC price

ns

ns

-

ns

-3.139

Feed price

ns

-5.120

-

0.60

-3.167

Wage rate

-3.527

-5.502

-0.620

-2.06

3.403

Lowest interest rate

ns

-6.265

ns

0.10

ns

Buildings and eqpt/Q

ns

-4.700

ns

ns

ns

Family labor/Q

1.741

2.057

0.334

1.075

-1.702

Land/Q

ns

-0.122

ns

0.012

ns

FCR

ns

ns

-0.593

-0.793

-0.397

Family labor x wage/Q

-0.775

-0.924

-0.162

-0.457

0.705

Buildings and eqmt/Q x wage rate

ns

1.658

ns

0.156

ns

Buildings and eqmt/Q x inter rate

ns

0.954

ns

-0.34

ns

Feed price x inter rate

ns

4.232

-

-0.18

ns

Fee contract Dummy

23.007

ns

-

17.64

17.618

Mean efficiency

0.578

0.506

0.839

0.595

0.827

log likelihood function

-69.06

-55.079

18.060

-36.85

21.370

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

Production arrangement effects: independent versus contract growers. Table 8.1.5 also shows the comparison of frontier estimation results between independents and contract growers. The following are the salient results:

Scale effects: smallholders versus commercial producers. Table 8.5 also presents the differential response of profit per kilogram to prices and fixed factors by smallholders and commercial producers. The following are the salient results:

In summary, smallholder profit per kilogram of output was determined by the price of broilers and day-old chicks and by investments in facilities and equipment, apart from whether or not one gets a fee contract. In contrast, commercial broiler producers' profits are most sensitive to changes in output and input prices.

Farm inefficiency and its determinants

The hypothesized determinants of farm technical/allocative inefficiency pertained to differential attributes of the decision-makers of the business. These embody differential human capital; differential access to markets, services, and information; and differential behavior in the mitigation of environmental externalities.

The pooled sample. Table 8.6 shows for the pooled sample the effect of the factors hypothesized as influencing farm inefficiency. The salient results are as follows:

Table 8.6 Determinants of inefficiency in broiler production, Philippines, 2002

EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Pooled

Independent and price contracts

Contract fee

Small- holders

Large/Commercial

Constant

ns

ns

ns

ns

2.445

Age

ns

ns

ns

ns

-0.842

Educ

ns

ns

ns

2.512

-2.058

Experience in poultry

ns

ns

ns

ns

0.660

Formal/informal training

ns

ns

ns

ns

-1.453

Picked up services by buyer

ns

ns

ns

ns

0.245

Has phone services (Info)

-1.535

ns

ns

-5.38

0.245

Environmental capture

ns

ns

ns

0.234

-0.237

Feeds credit dummy

-3.782

-3.132

-

-6.39

-2.340

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

Production arrangement effects: independents versus contract producers. Comparing the results on determinants of profit inefficiency (Table 8.6) between independents and fee contract growers, the following are observable:

Scale effects: smallholders versus commercial producers. Table 8.6 also shows the results on the determinants of technical/allocative efficiency between smallholders and commercial producers. The salient results are below:

Farm efficiencies of classes of broiler production, when family labor is not costedMean efficiency for the pooled sample was 0.58. Relative to this mean, efficiency levels varied among and within the producer classes. The following are the major results:

8.2 Hog Farms

8.2.1 Comparative profit performance

Profits by scale and production arrangement

Table 8.7 summarizes profits per kilogram of output and average farm profits by scale of production, with and without contracts. Observations include the following:

Table 8.7 Profit per kilogram of output and total farm profits, Hog Production Philippines, 2002

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<100 heads)

COMMERCIAL (100 heads and above)

Independent

Contract

Medium Independent

Large Independent

Contract

(PhP/kg)

26.69

2.08

19.43

20.37

2.33

Farm profits (PhP)

15,942

6,732

114,332

497,923

143,044

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03

Profit per kilogram and scale: by quintile

Figure 8.5 shows the behavior of profit per unit output by size quintile.

Figure 8.5 Profit per kilogram of output by size quintile, Hog Production, Philippines, 2002

The quintile distribution does not distinguish between independent producers (which generally earned higher profit per unit) and contract growers (which had uniformly lower profit margins). The following results are of interest:

8.2.2 Accounting for market distortions

Adjustments for cost of family labor

Figure 8.6 shows the behavior of profit per kilogram of output by size quintile, after the costing of family labor. The salient results are the following:

Figure 8.6 Average profit per kilogram after costing family labor, by quintile, Hog Production, Philippines 2002

Adjustments for the cost of environmental externalities

As in broiler production, adjustments for the cost of internalizing environmental externalities from animal wastes and mortalities were measured in terms of the value of manure sold or used on own farm, evaluated at market prices, and the cost of disposing of non-marketed or unused waste and animal carcasses. These were aggregated to comprise a measure of environmental abatement or mitigation expenditures per unit of output. The assumptions used for the validity of this measure are identical to those discussed in the broiler section.

Comparative expenditures on mitigation of environmental externalities. Table 8.8 presents the expenditures on environmental capture of externalities from waste and dead animals by smallholders and commercial producers of hogs, with and without contracts. The following are observed:

Table 8.8 Expenditure on mitigation of environmental externalities in hog production, by scale, with and without contracts, Philippines 2002

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<100 heads)

COMMERCIAL (100 heads and above)

Independent

Contract

Medium Independent

Large Independent

Contract

Expenditure per 100 kg output

57.3

4.1

17.1

27

4.1

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03

It does appear that independent producers tend to capture larger amounts of externalities from waste and dead animals than contract producers. It also appears that among independent producers, there are economies of scale in dealing with environmental capture.

Determinants of farm expenditure on mitigation of environmental externalities. Tobit regression was run to determine the differential effects of household, farm, and locational characteristics on mitigation expenditures by farm scale and production arrangement. The dependent variable is the total mitigation cost (pesos per kilogram of output), which is the sum of the following elements: the value of manure sold; the value of manure used on the farm; expenditures for disposal of dead animals; compensation to neighbors; transport costs associated with waste disposal; costs for licenses, taxes, and permits related to pollution; and depreciation and maintenance costs of waste treatment and control facilities. The explanatory variables include age and education of the household head or decision-maker (in years), the wage rate (pesos per hour), number of animal mortalities in the last cycle, distance to nearest residential community (in kilometers), size of inventory, feed conversion ratio (FCR), connection to piped-in water supply, and dummy variables for land classification, existence of croplands, location within Laguna Lake Development Authority (LLDA) jurisdiction, ability to sell manure in the last two months, and region (Bukidnon = 1).

Table 8.9 shows the results of the Tobit runs for the pooled sample. The important determinants of mitigation expenditure turned out to be three: existence of croplands, location within LLDA jurisdiction, and distance to the nearest residential community.

Table 8.9 Determinants of farm expenditure on mitigation of environmental externalities from hog production, Philippines, 2002.

EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Pooled Sample
N=203

All Indep. Farms
n=152

All Contract Farms
n=51

All Large Farms
n=95

Large Indep.
n=66

Small Indep
n=86

All Small Farms
n=108

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Coefficient

Education of HH head(yrs)

ns

ns

ns

0.017

0.028

ns

ns

Age of HH head (yrs)

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Able to sell manure in last2 mons. (Dummy)

ns

ns

0.104

ns

ns

3.678

3.695

Land class is Agricultural(Dummy)

ns

ns

0.060

ns

ns

ns

ns

Has crop land (Dummy)

0.501

0.578

ns

ns

ns

ns

0.917

Within LLDA jurisdiction(Dummy)

1.342

1.364

0.074

0.283

0.431

ns

ns

Wage rate (PhP per hr)

ns

ns

0.006

ns

ns

ns

ns

No. of mortalities in last cycle (heads)

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Distance to nearest Residential comm. (Kms)

0.010

ns

0.001

ns

-0.038

ns

ns

Connection to piped-in water supply

ns

ns

0.078

0.118

0.170

ns

ns

FCR-FE

ns

ns

ns

0.126

0.109

ns

ns

Size of inventory (no. of heads)

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Bukidnon (dummy)

ns

ns

ns

0.343

0.382

ns

ns

Constant

ns

ns

-0.143

-0.944

-1.070

ns

ns

Log pseudo-likelihood

-345.96

-279.36

33.01

-34.80

-26.50

-160.35

-191.23

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03.

The coefficient of the croplands dummy and the LLDA jurisdiction dummy carried the expected positive sign (as shifters of the intercept). Distance to the nearest residential community exhibited the sign opposite to that expected; the expectation was that farm proximity to population centers would prompt greater efforts to mitigate adverse environmental effects.

Regarding the effects of production arrangements, Table 8.9 also shows the Tobit results for the environmental capture regressions for all independents and all contract farms. The salient results are three:

Regarding scale effects, the Tobit results for large and small farms also yielded three main observations:

Looking at scale effects among independent farms, on average, independent hog farms were found to spend more per unit of output on environmental mitigation than contract farms. As a group, however, the cropland dummy was the only significant factor that appeared to explain the independent farms' mitigation expenditure behavior. However, small and large independent farms may respond differently to the factors hypothesized to explain environmental capture behavior.

Table 8.9 shows the Tobit results for small and large independents. The main results are the following:

Determinants of environmental mitigation behavior that turned out to be non-significant. Some of the hypothesized determinants of environmental mitigation behavior in hog production turned out to be non-significant. These fell into two groups. The first group is made up of the age of the farm decision-maker, the scale of operations (inventory size), and the number of animal mortalities. Although appearing only among medium and large independent farms, the level of education is more important than age, as such, in influencing environmentally relevant behavior. Scale had no systematic continuous effect on environmental mitigation, although small independent farms spent more than large producers on environmental mitigation per unit of output. Neither did the absolute number of animal mortalities on the farm appear to influence the level of environmental mitigation. This may simply imply that farms do not deal with the disposal of carcasses as an activity distinct and separable (as an environmental mitigation activity) from their normal production operations. Thus, only very slight variation that could be captured in explicit expenditures related to disposal of dead animals, regardless of scale.

The second group of non-significant factors is comprised by the wage rate and the official land classification (e.g., agricultural, residential, industrial). These determinants were insignificant to all except contract growers. Even for the contract group, the directional relation was opposite that hypothesized. It appears that the official classification of lands where hog farms are situated is irrelevant to hog farms inasfar as environmental mitigation behavior is concerned. The fact that a farm is situated on 'residential' or 'industrial' (non-agricultural) lands is not an automatic guarantee that the farmer will engage more intensively in environmentally friendly behavior. The mere classification of land as non-agricultural, without accompanying institutional pressures to define and enforce what pollutive activities are permitted, thus does not generate environmental mitigation activities on the part of farms.

Similarly, the wage rate appears to be non-significant in decisions on environmental mitigation expenditures, despite the hypothesis that the disposal and management of hog waste and dead animals is a labor-intensive activity. Perhaps this implies that factors other than the wage rate influence environmentally friendly behavior more.

Perverse responses in hypothesized determinants. Some perverse responses were observed in the hypothesized determinants of environmental mitigation behavior. First in this category are distance to residential areas and access to piped-in water supply. Distance to residential communities came out as significant only in the pooled sample and on contract farms and was insignificant for the others. Thus, the distance factor appears to work only with contract growers, but in a perverse way. Among contract farms, large-scale operations are, on average, farther away from residential centers than their smaller counterparts. But their mean expenditures on mitigation per kilogram of output are the same. Large fee contract farms are in fact governed by regulations on location requiring some minimum distance from other farms to control incidences of diseases. Moreover, incentives are provided (e.g., cost sharing) for spending on waste disposal facilities. Since the distance factor was not significant among small farms (including the small contract farms), the distance factor must be working on large contract farms. But the large contract farms are already, on average, farther away from residential communities. This distance variable may in fact be capturing something else, with an opposite effect on the environmental mitigation behavior than was hypothesized for pure distance.

The perverse effect of access to piped-in water supply applies to large farms and contract farms, but was non-significant among small farms. Access to piped-in water was hypothesized as allowing for easier, less costly disposal of hog waste from the pens to the nearest body of water through crude canals and gutters. The results, however, do not support the hypothesis. For large and contract producers, it appears that when access to piped-in water is present, they tend to make greater expenditures in controlling waste. Possibly, access to piped-in water enables them to build waste treatment facilities more easily, thus raising expenditures on environmental mitigation, all things being equal. Where there was no access to piped-in water, large farms and contract farms may try to minimize the flow of waste by non-capital-intensive means, for which costs are not explicit and thus were not captured by the survey instrument.

Conclusions on determinants of environmental capture on hog farms. From this discussion, a number of conclusions can be drawn regarding determinants of environmental capture on hog farms:

Policy implications. A few policy implications follow from the analyses described above. First, both market-based instruments and institutional pressures work in inducing environmentally relevant behavior. These two instruments, however, work differentially on smallholders and large producers. Smaller farms tend to respond to opportunities to sell manure or make use of it as fertilizer on their own farms and crops. Larger farms respond to the existence of an institution that makes and effectively enforces rules against environmental pollution.

Such formal institutional instruments work on large or commercial entities possibly because they are more easily targeted for the imposition of sanctions (as permit sources) and they have the size and capacity to invest in facilities and structures to minimize the potential magnitude of externalities on others. Moreover, the education of decision-makers appears to function positively for large producers. Likewise, the feed efficiency factor comes into play. This points to the potential of a technological-institutional approach to minimizing environmental pollution from commercial hog farms. If the technologies are developed, and are commercially supplied, when decision-makers are well informed and the rules are made clear in matters of environmental pollution, commercial producers are likely to respond by spending more per kilogram of output on environmental abatement.

Smallholders, on the other hand, will experience an institutional solution, such as enforcement of pollution standards, as an additional burden that increases their production costs. Nonetheless, they will respond if there are opportunities for them to benefit from the disposition of livestock waste, whether through the sale of manure or by its use on croplands. Since no functioning market for hog manure exists of the stature of the domestic chicken manure market, the policy direction suggested is, at the very least, the development of a feasible market for processed hog manure alongside increased access by smallholders to croplands. As with the broiler sample, hog-raising smallholders have the least access to manure markets even where they exist, and smallholders also tend to have very little assets in terms of agricultural cropland holdings.

Scale and environmental mitigation

Figure 8.7 shows the distribution of mitigation expenditures by scale of output. Farm expenditures per kilogram of output are higher among smallholders than among large producers. Those in the first quintile spend the most per kilogram of output, about 40 percent more than those in the second quintile and about eight times more than the third, fourth, and fifth quintiles.

Figure 8.7 Environmental mitigation cost by quintiles, Hog Production, Philippines, 2002

There appear to be economies of scale in environmental mitigation, as exhibited in the behavior of average cost of environmental mitigation, although average cost tends to remain constant after the third quintile. This can be understood in the context of the focus of expenditures on environmental mitigation by large commercial farms: in waste treatment facilities that are characterized as lumpy investments. The resort to such facilities, however, is viable only with sufficient scale of output.

Smallholders, particularly those with very small inventories and output per cycle must deal with the disposal of waste and dead animals using more labor-intensive methods. Where labor is not scarce, the smallholder would still end up spending more on environmental mitigation per unit of output by virtue of their smallness in scale.

Conclusions on scale and environmental mitigation. The analyses on scale and environmental mitigation show that small producers spend more per unit of output on environmental mitigation than large producers. But does this finding lead to the conclusion that smallholders pollute less than commercial (large-scale) producers?

Assuming that a unit of output (e.g., 100 kg) generates, on average, the same amount of physical waste and environmental cost, smallholders pollute less than large producers per unit of output under the condition that the value of environmental damage (cost) reduced per unit expenditure on environmental mitigation is the same. Under conditions where cost-effectiveness enters into the equation, and its direction with respect to scale is biased in favor of large-scale producers (third, fourth, and fifth quintiles), then smallholders still end up mitigating larger amounts of environmental cost per unit of output if the technologies of the large producers are only, at best, three times more cost-effective than the technologies or waste management and disposal practices that smallholders currently use. The already relatively high mitigation costs per unit of output internally borne by smallholders should warn against a strict and purely institutionalized approach to reducing environmental externalities from wastes in hog production.

The imposition of waste-treatment facilities (e.g. biogas digesters) on small-scale hog producers would further jack up their per unit expenditures on environmental mitigation, with direct adverse impacts on profits per unit output. This arises mainly from the lumpiness of such investments. A pure and strict institutional solution to environmental problems from hog waste would hit hardest operations where scale is small and constraints to expansion exist. The large producers at least have the scale to cushion the impact of large investments, other things being equal.

Trade and social subsidies to integrators and cooperatives

Differential access to credit. Table 8.10 shows the credit behavior of hog farmers. Differential access to formal credit is revealed in the lower incidence of borrowing for production purposes by smallholders (4-10%) compared to the group of large-scale farms (24-27%), as discussed in Chapter 5. This is reinforced by the relatively high percentage of smallholders who do not attempt to borrow from a bank because they perceive their chances of being granted a loan as being low (31%). Fewer commercial producers (19%) thought they would be ineligible for a bank loan.

The interest rates paid for loans averaged 17.6 percent per annum. There is no systematic pattern in the behavior of interest rates paid, except that among all groups the large independent producers obtained the lowest interest rate, at 15.6 percent per annum, while independent smallholders paid the highest average rate, at 18.2 percent.

Table 8.10 Borrowing experiences and perceptions on credit by hog farmers, Hog Production, Philippines, 2002.

ENTRY

SMALLHOLDER (<100 heads)

COMMERCIAL (100 heads and above)

Contract

Average

Independent

Contract

Medium Independent

Large Independent

Percent of farms that actually borrowed (%)

11.5

4.3

8.0

23.5

26.7

13.0

Average interest rate paid (% p.a.)

18.2

16.0

17.5

15.6

18.0

17.6

Percent of farms who believe they can get loan at 12% p.a., or less (%)

48.3

8.7

50.0

29.4

30.0

42.0

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03

There is no systematic pattern in which group has greater access to subsidized credit (12% rate or lower). Around half of the independent smallholders and medium-scale commercials believe they could access loans at that rate. Yet only about 30 percent of large commercial farms (independent and contract) perceived they could get those preferential rates.

Except for the smallholder contract growers, whose access to subsidized rates was also restricted, it appears that large-scale farms have less access to subsidized credit than small- and medium-scale farms. However, this distribution may be depicting the differential access to credit from sources other than banks, since credit sources such as friends and family might charge interest rates lower than 12 percent. Quite possibly, smallholders have greater access to informal sources of loans at lower than bank rates.

Subsidy on feeds and breeding stock to contract growers. The assertions made in the broiler section on the advantages conferred to large integrators due to their large stature apply to hog production as well. These advantages include access to minimum access volume (MAV) imports of corn at lower than regular tariff rates (35% vs. 60%); access to imported food wheat at tariff rates lower than feed wheat (3% vs. 10%); and access to duty-free imported breeding stock as a Board of Investment (BOI) incentive for locating operations in regions outside Metro-Manila.

The large integrators are said to pass on part of the benefits of such privileges to their commercial fee contract growers. These take the form of a higher fixed fee base per kilogram of output than could be the case had the advantages not been enjoyed.

Feed and credit subsidy to smallholder price contract growers of feed-milling and multipurpose cooperatives. The assertions in the broiler section on the advantages of feed-milling and multipurpose cooperatives engaged in livestock contract growing generally applies to hog production as well. This advantage arises from the cooperatives' exemption from the corporate income (profits) tax, levied on corporations and business entities at 32 percent of net income.

An example of a multipurpose feed-milling cooperative engaged in hog contract growing that enjoys such a privilege is the Soro-Soro Ibaba Development Cooperative (SIDC) in Batangas City in Southern Luzon. As of 2002, it had 322 contract growers, 287 of which were grow-to-finish hog raisers, 265 broiler raisers, and 9 farrow-to-weaning hog farmers. The SIDC incurred a net loss of 9.6 million pesos in 2002 due to very high production costs. Therefore, to illustrate the potential magnitude of the cooperative's implicit subsidy, SIDC's net income in 2000 is used (Table 8.11).

The cooperative earned a total net income of 33.9 million pesos in 2000, about 75 percent of which was generated by its main activity, feed milling. Its contract growing operation was only fourth in the order of net income contribution, accounting for only about three percent of cooperative net income. If the regular corporate tax rate of 32 percent were imposed on the total net income of 33.9 million pesos, then the tax bill would have been 10.9 million pesos in 2000. This is the equivalent implicit subsidy (tax exemption) which corporate feed-milling firms of similar size engaging (or not engaging) in contract growing do not enjoy. The magnitude of this implicit subsidy (10.9 million pesos) is even larger than the absolute contribution of the contract growing operations of the cooperative to overall net income (1.0 million pesos).

Table 8.11 Net income and implicit subsidy on SIDC feedmilling, contract growing, and other operations, 2000

Activity/Source

Net Income (PhP Million)

Percent Share of Net Income (%)

Implicit Subsidy (PhP Million)

Feed milling

25.3

74.6

8.10

Mini-mart

7.7

22.7

2.46

Expanded credit line

1.1

3.2

0.35

Contract growing

1.0

2.9

0.32

TOTAL NET INCOME

33.9


10.85

Source: Annual Report, SIDC, 2001.

The SIDC considers its contract growing operations to be a social program to build goodwill among the nearby communities. The apparent 'insignificance' of the contribution of the contract growing to total net income gives the cooperative leeway to 'subsidize' this activity from its larger and more important profit centers.

8.2.3 Determinants of technical/allocative efficiency

As with broiler farms, profit frontiers were estimated for hog production. With the frontier determined, the efficiency level of the farm classes was established and the effects of the variables hypothesized to influence farm efficiency estimated.

Effects of prices, fixed factors, and technology

Table 8.12 presents the estimated profit frontier and determinants of technical/allocative efficiency among hog farms. For the pooled sample, the following are the salient points:

Table 8.12 Determinants of profit and inefficiency, Hog production, Philippines, 2002

EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Pooled
(N=207)

All Independents
(N=154)

All Contracts
(N=53)

All Small-holders
(N=110)

All Large-scale
(N=97)

Constant

3.564

ns

2.412

ns

ns

Price of hogs

0.685

1.233

1.08

0.789

1.506

Price of piglets

0.727

0.738

-

1.110

-0.495

Price of weanlings

-0.119

-0.119

-0.266

-0.116

-

Price of feed

-0.687

-0.718

-0.814

-0.696

-0.544

Contract dummy

-0.405

-

-

-0.373

3.227

Wage rate

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Free board and lodging dummy

ns

ns

ns

-0.106

ns

Lowest interest rate

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Value of inventory/Q

ns

ns

ns

0.018

ns

Buildings and eqpt /Q

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Family labor /Q

ns

ns

ns

-0.379

ns

Farmsize (in ha)/Q

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

FCR

ns

ns

ns

ns

-0.115

mortality rate

ns

ns

-0.0178

ns

ns

Family labor x wage rate

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Buildings and eqpt /Q x lowest I.r.

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

farrow-wean dummy

ns

2.315

-

ns

8.695

combined farrow-wean and farrow-finish

-2.986

-3.012

-

-4.599

2.555

Very large dummy

-

-

-

-

ns

Constant

-6.594

-1.978

ns

ns

2.197

Age

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Experience in hog business

ns

-0.426

0.102

ns

ns

Education

ns

ns

ns

ns

ns

Formal/informal training

2.052

2.833

ns

1.799

ns

Feeds credit dummy

ns

1.086

0.271

2.220

ns

Capital credit dummy

-1.448

-0.986

-0.161

-1.945

ns

Information

-4.972

-3.078

0.702

-3.665

ns

Buyer is viajero

4.12

2.08

-

2.857

ns

Environmental cost

ns

-0.77

-0.106

-1.217

ns

Fee contract dummy

-1.391

-

-0.747

-

-1.838

Very large dummy

-

-

-

-


Region dummy (Bukidnon=1)

ns

-1.41

ns

ns

-0.703

sigma squared

2.085

1.357

0.0127

1.583

0.203

gamma

0.994

0.992

0.7

0.997

0.984

Mean efficiency

0.802

0.781

0.746

0.802

0.812

Source: UPLB-IFPRI LI Field Survey, 2002-03

Effects of production arrangements: independent versus contract production.

For independent producers, the two relevant activity type dummies were significant-farrow-to-weaning (Type 1) and dual output (Type 4). Other things being equal, average profit per unit was higher on farms engaging in farrow-to-weaning activity; but profit per unit was lower on farms engaging in Type 4 activity (combined operations).

Scale effects: smallholders versus large-scale producers.

Determinants of technical/allocative efficiency

The pooled sample.

Production arrangement impacts: independent producers versus contract growers.

Scale effects: smallholders versus large-scale producers.

Comparative efficiency among hog farms

Figure 8.8 shows the efficiency levels achieved by size quintile.

Figure 8.8 Mean efficiency among hog farms by size quintile, Hog Production, Philippines, 2002

Scale effects: comparative efficiency by size quintile.


Previous Page Top of Page Next Page