Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


VIII. Stochastic Profit Frontier Estimation for Swine


This study attempts to apply the stochastic frontier function to the profit equation. One can use an analogy of the "ideal" production function to argue that in a world with no transaction cost, there would be an ideal profit function. However, there are two main problems. Firstly, there is no strong theoretical support for such an analogy. Profits are not only determined by the revenue and costs of production, which in turn depends partly upon the production function, but are also significantly influenced by the random factors (or "pure luck"). Most, if not all, entrepreneurs are successful not only because of their ability but also because of luck. Moreover, if we assume zero transaction cost, the economists' definition of profit would have to change. Profits are not simply the residual after all the factors of production are paid for their services. They are the return to risk - taking activity of the entrepreneur. In a world with perfect knowledge and zero transaction cost, there would be no economic profit. Therefore, our profit frontier would be zero.

However, we can argue that the ideal profit is the maximum profit received by "the best entrepreneur" with the highest ability in management and best luck in risk-taking. As a result, the frontier function can be readily applied to estimate the frontier profit.

The second problem is an empirical issue. Our main interests in explaining the differentials in farms' profit cover three major issues, namely, the scaling up of production by structural factors (particularly technology and transaction costs), the externalities and the policy distortions. Our hypothesis is that technological change, the public concern about the negative impact of externalities generated by the pig farms, and some government policies are biased against the small-scale farms. In the estimated profit frontier function, therefore, it is postulated that profit depends upon environmental cost, prices of inputs, prices of output, fixed factors, and other exogenous variables such as farm characteristics, government policies and factors affecting farmers' transaction costs (see the list of independent variables in Table 8.5).

8.1 Estimation Problems

In estimating of the profit frontier, there are some problems with some independent variables and the dependent variable. The independent variables have the following problems: the cost of environmental abatement suffers the endogeneity problem; the problems arising from the fact that the contract farmers do not buy their inputs, e.g. feeds and piglets; and the problems of imputing the wage for the farms that employ only family workers.

8.1.1 The Net Revenue Per Unit of Output

The dependent variable is defined as the net profit per kilogram of output sold. Net profit is the revenue from the swine-growing activities - both direct and by-product income - minus the variable costs. But there are two problems.

The first problem is that our sample consists of 3 groups of farm holders, i.e., the independent growers, the price-guarantee contractees and the wage contract farmers. The letter does not make profit. Instead, they receive fixed wage per kilogram of live pigs (or fixed wage per live piglets) they successfully grow. There are 30 wage contract farms out of 174 sample pig farms. Their net revenue is not the same as the net profit received by the other two groups of farmers, but is defined as the wage income minus the costs of variable inputs, excluding the costs of feeds, piglets and drugs which are paid by their contractor. The variable costs of the wage contractees include labor, utilities, tax, and interest payment.

Since the net revenue received by the wage contractees is not the same as the net profit, the dependent variable has to be re-defined as the net revenue per kilogram of output. Then all the sample farms are pooled in the estimation of the frontier net revenue function. Yet, since the behavior of the wage contract farmers are different from the others, this study also separate the sample into two groups in the estimation of the profit frontier.

The second problem is caused by the fact that a small number of independent farms reported negative profit. To be able to run the profit frontier function, the revenue per unit has to be adjusted upward by a fixed proportion K. It is defined as the highest number that will make the net profit of the farms reporting loss become one or higher.

For the wage contract farms, the adjustment is different. The gross fee is adjusted upward by the difference in the independent farms per unit profit before and after the adjustment by K.

8.1.2 The Cost of Environmental Abatement

One main interest of this study concerns the impact of the environmental abatement on farms' profit. But the cost of environmental abatement is subject to endogeneity problem. The environmental cost does not only affect profit but may also be affected by the farm's profit. This study will use an instrumental variable approach to tackle the problem of the correlation between the disturbances and environmental cost (see the estimated results and discussion below).

8.1.3 Missing Information on Key Input Prices in the Profit Function

The second problem is a possibility of upward bias of the estimated coefficients of the feed prices. Some high caliber farmers may choose to use the high quality feed as they expect the extra revenue from high quality feed is higher than the extra cost. Ideally, some independent measure of feed quality should be included in the first stage of the profit frontier function (SPF), but that is not possible due to lack of data. The only independent measure of feed quality is the dummy variables representing the type of contractual arrangements.

However, there is another issue relating the quality of feed to the type of farms. The survey finds that all of the contract farms have to pay higher prices for their feeds, while the price-guarantee contract farms also receive higher-than-market prices for their pigs sold to the contractor. Moreover, the wage contract farmers do not have to buy any variable input, because the contractor provides them. Therefore, there are no input prices for those wage contract farms, particularly the prices of feeds and the prices of piglets. This study uses two approaches to tackle the problems. The first approach is to assign the value of zero for the prices of feeds and piglets for the contract farms. But then a dummy variable representing "contract farm" should be added in the first stage of the profit frontier (SPF) to control for the fact that contract farms have different relationship between input prices and output prices from the independent farms.

The second approach is to obtain the prices of inputs directly from the contractors. Although the input prices may not directly affect the production costs of the contractee, they may indirectly affect his/her income from the contract. In the wage contract, the contractor has to bear most of the production and price risks. So he will have to charge his contractee higher input prices in his contract account to compensate for the higher risk. But the higher the input prices, the lower the contract wage will be. Since different contractors charge different input prices, the wage income of the contractees will be different. Therefore, the input prices faced by the wage contractors are defined to include the 'accounting prices' charged by the contractor on his contractees' account. The input price data are obtained from the contractors. The net revenue for these wage contract farms is still the actual revenue reported by the farmers. To control for the differences in the relationship between net revenue and input prices of the contractees and the independent farms, the profit function will have to include the interaction terms between the contract dummy and the input prices. Moreover, since the price-guarantee contract farmers also have to buy inputs from the contractor at higher-than-market price and receive the fixed guarantee price for their output, two more interaction terms are included in the profit function, i.e., the interaction between the price guarantee dummy and the feed price, and the interaction between the price guarantee dummy and the pig (output) price.

8.1.4 Imputing Wage in the Profit Function

While most pig farms employ hired labor - both on the daily and monthly basis - many of them, particularly the small farms also use family labor. For those who do not have hired labor, there will be no reported wage rate. This study will use the average provincial wage rate as a proxy for the wages of the family workers. The average wage is the average wage of the hired workers in the pig farms in each province[113]. We do not use zero wages as in the case of prices of piglets and prices of feeds. In the latter case, the wage contract farms do not buy the inputs. In the case of family labor, the farms owner has to pay their family workers some living allowances-either in-kind or in-cash. But the wages paid may not relate to the productivity of those family workers.

Another problem is the multicollinearity problem caused by the high correlation between the family workers and the market wages. Although the problem will reduce the estimated significance of the coefficients of family labor and wage rate, it is not the main concern of this study. Our focus is to obtain the unbiased residuals of the first stage of the profit function.

8.1.5 Non-Neutral Technical Change

Another main issue of this study is to explore the impact of technological change on the growth of the livestock sector. In the modern swine industry, technological changes do not occur as one major change, but instead they consist of a series of improvements. In the last two decades, one has seen the improvement of imported breeders from Europe, an introduction of the evaporative housing to control the temperature in the pig housing, the improvement in feeds (see Poapongsakorn et.al., 2002). Moreover, the widespread of pig-growing training has allowed farmers to develop deeper tacit knowledge of how to properly grow pigs. As a result, the farmers who have adopted those technological changes have experienced a decline in feed conversion ratio which significantly boost their profit. This study, therefore, will use the feed conversion ratio as the proxy of non-neutral technological change.

8.2 Instrumental Variables for Pollution Abatement Cost

Among farms in the livestock sector, the swine farms are probably the largest source of pollution in term of air, water and soil. Recently the rapid expansion of the swine industry, fuelled by rising income, growing urbanization, and technological change, has resulted in more serious negative impacts on the environment. Since most farms locate in the peri-urban areas and many farms are near the rivers, they are subject to complaints from the nearby community. The complaints include the bad smelt, flies and polluted canals and rivers. As a result, increasing number of farms begin in invest in pollution abatement activities. Fore example our swine farm survey shows that about 30 percent of the sample farms have invested in the water treatment ponds. The annual cost of pollution abatement per ton of pig sold is 1,458 baht per farms per year, and it varies negatively with farm size (measured in terms of stock of pigs, see Table 8.1). But the abatement cost per farm varies positively with farm size. There are as many as 64 farms that do not have any abatement cost. The question is whether or not farm size matters after other independent variables are controlled for.

Pollution abatement is defined as the marginal cost of abatement effort and the fixed costs of equipment and capital used for pollution control. The variable cost includes labor hire to get rid of manure and cost of chemicals and organism. The fixed costs are calculated as the annual depreciation. The value of the manure sold is also included as part of the abatement cost because the farmers have to incur extra cost of getting rid of manure. Finally, the abatement cost is divided by the quantity of pig sold to control for the size of farm. The independent variables are also standardized. The definitions of all the variables are given in Table 8.2.

Since the dependent variable series contains either zero or positive value, the Tobit technique is used to estimate the pollution abatement cost function.

The result is shown in Table 8.3. The coefficient of herd size is negative, but not statistically significant. Though the result is consistent with the cross-tab in Table 8.1, it is contrary to our expectation that the larger farm should invest more in pollution abatement. One possible reason is that pigs are not exported and hence the large companies are not subject to pressure from the foreign buyers. The Thai customers have not yet using their buying power to pressure the swine farms to invest in pollution abatement activities. Those who complain about the pollution problems are people who live near the farm. The complaints are mostly against the small farmers who tend to locate their farms near the village or the town. Yet the distance from the community (DISTVIL) is not significant. While the number of complaints by the nearby villagers is not significant, farmers who have engaged in activities to reduce the number of flies (FLIES) are found to invest more in pollution control. One surprising result is that farms that are farther away from river or canal (DISTVIL) tend to incur higher abatement costs. This may imply that if there is no nearby waterway, then the farmers will have to invest in pollution abatement to avoid having conflicts with the villagers.

The access to long-term credit (LTCREDIT), measure as the ratio of long-term credit to total borrowing, is significantly positive. Moreover, the farms that receive government subsidy (SUBS) to build water treatment ponds or biogas digester tend to invest more in pollution abatement. The results imply that the market failure is the significant factor contributing to negative externalities. Government subsidy and intervention in the credit market can significantly alleviate the negative effects. Farms that have income from crops (CROP) tend to invest more in pollution abatement because manure can be used on their farms. Those with non-farm income (NONFARM) may have enough capital to invest in the pollution abatement activities.

Finally, it should be noted that most of the variables measuring personal characteristics, e.g. age, education, and experience, are not statistically significant. Nor are the provincial dummy variables.

8.3 The Estimation of Stochastic Frontier Function

Each type of swine farm has different cost and revenue structure. For the independent farm, the piglet farms seem to make more profit per kilogram of pig sold than the fattening farms (Table 8.4). Among the independent piglet farms, the medium-scale farms tend to make the highest profit. The lower-medium-scale piglet farms under the price guarantee contract also make more profit than other farms. The observation that the lower-medium-scale farms make the highest profit is consistent with the fact that weaning piglets is a highly care-intensive but the farms have to be large enough to exploit the scale economies in the production process and input purchasing. For the independent fattening farms, the larger farms make more profit than the smaller ones. The large-scale fattening farms under the wage contract also make more net revenue than the smaller farms. Therefore, fattening activities are subject to economies of scale.

Given the above information on profit, it seems logical to estimate the separate profit frontier function for the fattening farms and the piglet farms since they have different production functions. However, since twenty-eight farms grow both piglets and fattened pigs, both activities can be considered as parts of the same production process. Therefore, we will estimate both fattening and the piglet farms.

The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of net revenue per kilogram of pig sole, where the net revenues for the independent farmers and the contract farmers are defined above.

The independent variables can be classified into two groups, i.e., those determining the profit frontier (or the first stage profit frontier, SPF) and the transactions cost that affect the efficiency of each farm. The former consists of the following variables: prices of pig sold per kilogram (output), prices of major variable inputs (wage rate, feeds and piglet), fixed inputs per kilogram of output (capital and family labor), a proxy for technological change (LFEEDC) and the dummy variables representing different production relation among farms (see list of variables in Table 8.5).

The proxies for transaction costs are as follows: personal characteristics of the farmers which are proxies of ability and know-how, e.g., education, age and experience of the farm owner; credit constraint; transportation costs (such as distance from the community); density of pig farms; government services; and regional dummies.

All of the above independent variables, except the dummies, are in natural logarithm (see Table 8.5 for definitions).

The results in Table 8.6 show that the stochastic frontier estimation is statistically significant as shown by the value of Wald Chi-Square. The estimated value of is also significantly different from zero, suggesting that the technical efficiency equation can explain the difference between each farm's profit and the profit on the frontier function. Gamma is 0.83 and significant, suggesting that some variations in farms' profits are caused by the transaction costs.

The estimates show that the output price (LPRICEPIG) has positive and significant impact on farm profit. The feed price (LFEEDP) coefficient is weakly significant and has the expected negative sign. The price of piglet (LPIGLET) also has the negative and significant coefficient. Wages (LWAGE2) are not significant because it is highly correlated with family labor. The capital (LCAPITAL) and family labor (LFMILY) coefficients are positive but not significant. Other dummy variables controlling for the contractual arrangement (CONTRAC1, GUARANTEE) and nature of farm integration (full cycle farm or FCYCLE) are not significant, except the dummy variable representing the piglet farm (BABY). But the most robust parameter is the feed conversion ratio (LFEEDC) that has the expected sign. The higher the feed used to produce one kilogram of pig meat, the lower the profit. This means that the farmers who adopt the best technology in pig production will make more profit. Another interpretation is that farmer with better management capability (or know- how) can make higher profit.

The technical efficiency equation also yields satisfactory result. It should be noted that the positive coefficient represents inefficiency (value of m) because the value of u would be higher when the farm is farther away below the profit frontier. The higher the cost of environmental abatement (PRE-ENVM2), the lower the profit is. Older farmers (LAGEHH) and farms in the East and the Central regions are less efficient. Although formal education (LYEAREDU) is not significant, farmers who receive training (TRAINING) in pig production are more efficient.

The more efficient farms are those that are far from the town (LVILLKM), far from the slaughterhouse (LSLAVGHKM) and farmers who seek advice from the consultant, pig manual or the contractor (MANAGA). Perhaps, the farms that are far from the community and the old slaughterhouse may be the new farms with modern equipment.

Farms that invest more in environmental abatement seem to make less profit since preenvm2 is positive and significant. Farms that buy feeds on credit term (CREDIT) are also more efficient.

Other independent variables are not statistically significant. They include gender of the farm owner (FEMALE), owner's farm experience (LEXPERHH), farm density within 1 square km. (LDENFARM), credit constraint (CRECONST), farms that sell pigs directly to the slaughterhouse or food processors (TRANPRO), and these receiving government services (SERVICE) or having good ventilation system for their pig house (VENTIL), or those changing feed formula last year (CHANGFED).

Table 8.7 also gives another set of frontier estimation with separate prices of two kinds of feeds, i.e., mixed feeds and ready-to-use feeds produced by the feed manufacturers. But the results are not better than the estimation with one feed price.

Table 8.8 presents another set of profit frontier estimation which uses different definitions of input prices, i.e., the input prices of contract farms are not zero but are assigned the value of the average price for each province. In the estimation, several interaction terms between the type of farm and the input and output prices are also included. But the results are not much different from those in Table 8.6. The only interesting result is that the interaction of price-guarantee contract and the pig price (GUAPRIC) is positive and significant, while the price of pig (LPRICPIG) is still significant, but with slightly higher coefficient. This means that the guarantee contract farms that have higher guarantee price will have higher profit than other farms. After the control, the price of pig has larger positive effect on farms' profit.

Although the farm size is not included in the profit frontier function because there is already a proxy of non-constant technological change in the estimation (i.e., logarithm of feed conversion ratio), one can calculate the technical efficiency by farm size. The TE 2 produced by STATA has the value between 1 and 0, with one as the most efficient. The estimates in Table 8.9 show that the large-scale farms have higher efficiency than other farms, while the efficiency of the small- and the medium-scale farms are not different. The results are different from the simple cross tabulation of profit and farm size in Table 8.4. Therefore, after controlling for the independent variables affecting profit, the large-scale farms are relatively more efficient. The findings are consistent with casual observation that in the recent years the average swine farm size has become larger.

8.4 The Profit Frontier of Two Different Types of Farms

As mentioned above, the piglet farms and the fattening farm have different production functions. While the piglet farms are relatively care-intensive activity, the fattening farms are more labor-intensive requiring the employment of unskilled or semi-skilled workers to feed the pigs and to clean the pens on the fixed schedule basis. Thus, the fattening farms can exploit the economies of scale by investing in laborsaving technology. The tasks that are subject to economies of scale include bulk purchasing of inputs, feed mixing process, automatic feeding process and large quantity of pig sold each time. However, the full-circle pig farms still have to grow breeders and wean piglets. Currently more and more large farms tend to separate their piglet farms from the fattening farms by separating the farmhouses or even locating their farms in different location so that the disease problems in one farm do not spread to the others. Unfortunately, our farm survey cannot obtain separate set of financial data for those two types of farms.

Given such constraint, we estimate two profit functions; one for the piglet farm and the other for the fattening farms that sell only fattened pigs. The latter includes both the full-cycle farms (from farrows to finish) and the wean-to-finish farms. The estimated results for piglet farms are shown in Table 8.10. The results are similar to the pooled profit frontier estimation, but the estimates, which contain one variable of feed prices, are slightly better than the one that has two-price variable because the Wald Chi Square is higher.

There are a few interesting results. First, the piglet farms that incur pollution abatement costs are not less efficient than those that do not invest. This is opposite to the pooled estimation. Secondly, family labor (LFAMILY) and capital (CAPITAL) have positive and significant coefficients despite the fact that the wage rate is not significant. Using more family workers can increase profit because the breeder farms are too care-intensive to depend on hired labor. Moreover, the modern breeder farms tend to invest more in the breeder housing and pens so that they can maintain the high degree of hygiene. The price-guarantee farms also receive higher profit. Thirdly, only a few independent variables, which are the proxies for transaction costs, are significant. Though age, education, and experience are not significant, training enables the farmers to make more profit. Farmers who changed the feed formula in the survey year are also more efficient. Farms in the central region (CENTRAL) are also more efficient. But it is very strange that the credit constraint variable (CRECONSI) is negative and significant. Finally, the estimates of the technical efficiency by farm size show that the farms with 101-500 pigs are the most efficient (see Table 8.9). The estimation is consistent with the actual profit shown in Table 8.4.

Most of the profit frontier estimates for the fattening farms are not satisfactory as gamma is almost one, implying that the transaction costs play no role in explaining variation in profits across farms. Fortunately, one specification yields some satisfactory results (in term of LR test and value of gamma), though most of the variables in the first stage of the profit frontier estimation are not significant. In this specification, the feed price has non-zero value and several interactions between the type of contract farm and the prices of inputs or the price of output are included. The results are given in Table 8.11. All of the input and pig prices are not significant. Even the feed conversion ratio (LFEEDC) is not significant. There are only two significant variables in the first stage, i.e., the price guarantee contract dummy and the interaction between the price guarantee contract and the pig price.

Farms that invest more in the environmental abatement are less efficient which are proxies of transaction costs are significant, suggesting that the price variables and technological change play almost no role in explaining variation in farm profits.

The technical efficiency (Table 8.9) also shows that the large farms are more efficient than the small farms.

Table 8.1 Average Cost of Pollution Abatement for Swine

Farm Size

Average Cost Baht/farm/year

Cost per ton of pigs Baht/ton/year

No. of farms incurring abatement cost

No.of farms with no abatement costs

small 1-100

3,589.7

2,635.6

1,317.8

10

10

medium low 101-500

5,204.1

1,799.1

1,156.6

45

25

medium high 501-1000

1,220.0

1,087.5

795.7

30

11

large > 1000

32,708.6

816.9

474.9

25

18

total

13,216.3

1,457.8

921.6

110

64

Source: TDRI, Livestock Farm Survey, December 2002.

Table 8.2 Variable List in the Environmental Cost Regressions

Variable Name

Definition

Unit

enco_v

cost of environment abatement per pig ton sole (not include manure sale)

baht/year/ton of pig

enco_vm

cost of environment abatement per pig ton sole (include manure sale)

baht/year/ton of pig

herd

number of pigs (total pig) in farm

pigs

agehh

age of farm owner

years

female

female farm owner

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

yearedu

education of farm owner

years

socstat

social status in a community, e.g. holding position in local administration office

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

distvil

distance to nearest village

km.

distriv

distance to nearest river

km.

density

pigs density in the radius 1 kilometer

pigs

flies

putting effort in reducing the amount of flies

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

yearfarm

Years of farm breeding swine

years

ltcredit

share of long term credit to total borrowing


crop

other income from crop

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

fish

other income from fish

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

nonfarm

other income from non-farm

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

subs

environmental subsidy

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

chachern

chachernsoa province

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

lopburi

lopburi province

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

cholburi

cholburi province

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Note: Costs of environmental abatement include variable cost (labor and others) and fixed cost (amortized value). Fixed inputs are water tanks, water treatment ponds, bio-gas ponds, water pipes.

Table 8.3 Estimation of Cost of Environmental Abatement


Number of obs = 174

Log likelihood = -1340.4716

LR chi2(16) = 27.80


Prob > chi2 = 0.0334


Pseudo R2 = 0.0103

Dependent = enco_vm


Coef.

t

herd

0.0259423

0.19 (n.s.)

agehh

-7.444848

-0.35 (n.s.)

female

726.1465

1.75

yearedu

19.95371

0.37 (n.s.)

socstat

81.5949

0.17 (n.s.)

distvil

-1.502896

-0.02 (n.s.)

distriv

43.99518

2.17

density

-0.0247667

-0.72 (n.s.)

flies

-24.05543

-0.06 (n.s.)

yearfarm

-9.51647

-0.40 (n.s.)

ltcredit

4.749874

1.19 (n.s.)

crop

1052.606

1.77 (n.s.)

fish

-291.1475

-0.37 (n.s.)

nonfarm

1038.916

1.82

subs

1277.99

3.22

chachern

756.1432

1.78

cons

-426.582

-0.32 (n.s.)

se

2265.636


Obs. Summary: 29 left-censored observations at encovm<=0
144 uncensored observations
1 right-censored observation at encovm>=18505.05

Table 8.4 Net Revenue Per Kilogram of Pig by Farm Type

profit (baht/ton of pig)

Farm Type

small 1-100

medium low 101-500

Medium high 501-1000

large > 1000

total

mean

n

mean

n

Mean

n

mean

n

mean

n

independent farms

11,949.6

18

19,998.6

42

14,243.2

26

15,407.4

40

15,582.0

126

contract


0

2,734.6

17

1,208.1

9

1,722.7

3

1,815.8

29

guarantee price

11,505.9

2

20,180.6

11

13,697.3

6


0

17,138.9

19

total

11,902.7

20

15,390.3

70

11,006.0

41

14,979.5

43

14,257.3

174

piglet

12,875.1

7

33,758.3

36

22,727.1

8

11,130.7

3

27,203.4

54

fattening swine

4,302.7

10

9,124.9

27

9,372.7

25

14,916.6

30

13,040.3

92

piglet and fattening

26,756.8

3

10,751.5

7

12,616.1

8

15,252.7

10

14,858.2

28

total

11,902.7

20

15,390.3

70

11,006.0

41

14,979.5

43

14,257.3

174

independent farms











piglet

13,596.8

5

35,143.5

21

25,072.6

6

11,130.7

3

28,056.4

35

fattening

4,302.7

10

12,127.1

14

13,245.6

13

15,540.0

27

14,934.8

64

piglet and fatten

26,756.8

3

10,751.5

7

11,967.2

7

15,252.7

10

14,802.6

27

total

11,949.6

18

19,998.6

42

14,243.2

26

15,407.4

40

15,582.0

126

wage contract farm











piglet


0

14,551.4

10


0


0

14,551.4

10

fattening


0

1,421.4

7

1,208.1

9

1,722.7

3

1,385.4

19

piglet and fatten


0


0


0


0


0

total


0

2,734.6

17

1,208.1

9

1,722.7

3

1,815.8

29

guaranteed price contract











piglet

11,505.9

2

41,712.1

5

11,477.4

2


0

27,699.2

9

fattening


0

15,581.2

6

13,032.4

3


0

14,476.8

9

piglet and fatten


0


0

21,818.8

1


0

21,818.8

1

total

11,505.9

2

20,180.6

11

13,697.3

6


0

17,138.9

19

Source: Calculate from the Household Farm Survey, 2002.

Table 8.5 Variable List in the Profit Model

Variable Name

Definition

Unit

note

Ladjprof

ln (profit per pig ton sale)

bant/month/ton of pig sold

Lfeedp

ln (feed price)

bant/ton of pig

price = 0 for contrac farm

Lmixp

ln (price of mixed feeds)

bant/ton of pig

price = 0 for contrac farm

Lredp

ln (price of ready mixed feeds)

bant/ton of pig

price = 0 for contrac farm

Lfeedp1

ln (feed price)

bant/ton of pig

market price for contrac farm

Lmixp1

ln (price of mixed feeds)

bant/ton of pig

market price for contrac farm

Lredp1

ln (price of ready mixed feeds)

bant/ton of pig

market price for contrac farm

Lwage2

ln (wage of hired employee)

bant/month


Lpricepig

ln (price of pig sale)

bant/ton of pig


Lpiglet1

ln (price of piglect)

bant/ton of pig


Lfamily

ln (number of family workers)

persons/ton of pig


Lland

ln (land area of the farm)

rais/ton of pig


Lcapital1

ln (amortzed value of building & capital per pig ton sold1)

baht/year/ton


Lfixinv

ln (capital + land rent)2

baht/year/ton of pig

Lfeedc

ln (feed conversion)



Contrac1

wage contract farm

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Guarante

price - guarantee contract farm

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Fcircle

fully circle farm

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Baby

piglet farm only

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Confed

contrac1 * lfeedp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Conmix

contrac1 * lmixp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Conred

contrac1 * lredp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Guafed

guarantee * lfeedp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Guamix

guarantee * lmixp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Guared

guarantee * lredp1

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Guapri

guarantee * lprice pig

interaction (baht/ton of pig)

Lagehh

ln (age of farm owner)

years


Lyearedu

ln (education of farm owner)

years


Lexperhh

ln (experience of farm owners)

years


Female

female farm owner

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Training

attended any training programs

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Manage

advice for breeding pig

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Lvillkm

distance from community

km


Ldenfarm

farm density in the radius 1 kilometer

km


Lslaughkm

distance from slaughterhouse

km


Ventil

good ventilation housing

dummy 0, 1


Changfed

selling pigs directly to processors

dummy 0, 1


Service

changing feed formula last year

dummy 0, 1


Tranpro

processing house for domestic and export market

dummy 0, 1


Credit

buying feed on credit term

dummy 0, 1


Creconst

plans increasing investment but lack of capitals

dummy 0, 1


East

receiving government serios

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Central

central region

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Genera

inherit this farm from your relative

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Higedu

tertiary education

dummy: 0 = no; 1 = yes

Higedgen

highedu * genera

interaction term


pre_envm2




Note (1) Annual depreciation with following assumptions

- Cost for open housing at 20 years
- Cost for evap housing at 20 years
- Cost for office and home office at 30 years
- Cost for feed mixing building at 20 years
- Cost for manure, fences, water tanks at 10 years
- Cost for water treatment, bio-gas at 15 years

(2) Since there is no direct questions on the definitions of full-cycle and wean-to-finish farms, the definition has to be determined from 2 questions in the questionnaire, i.e., (1) what type of pigs do you sell? And (2) the stock of pigs classified by type of pigs.

Stock of pigs (a7)

Type of pigs sold (a1)

Piglets

Fattened pigs

Both

Breeders and weaners

1

2 -

3 -

BABY (a1 = 1)



Breeders, weaners, fattened

4 -

5

6


Full cycle (a1 = 2)

Full cycle (a1 = 3 or 4)

Weaner and fattened

7 -

8

9 -


wean-to-finish (a1 = 5)


Full-cycle farms

= farms in box no. 5, and 6

(f-cycle = 1, 0)


Wean-to-finish farms

= farms in box no. 8

(reference)


Farms selling piglets only

= farms in box no.1

(baby = 1, 0)


Table 8.6 Results of Profit Frontier Estimation: Pooled Sample

Model 1 (output from the program STATA)

Stoc. frontier normal/truncated-normal model

Number of obs = 171


Wald chi2(11) = 366.77

Log likelihood = -39.339306

Prob > chi2 = 0.0000


STATA OUPTPUT

FRONTIER OUTPUT

Coef.

z

P>|z|

Coeff

t-ratio

ladjprof

lfeedp

-.0572472

-0.83

0.404

0.87375029E+01

0.85810655E+01

lwage2

-.0521568

-0.57

0.565

-0.71046671E-01

-0.10634621E+01

lpricpig

.3311465

5.32

0.000

-0.89189185E-01

-0.94893410E+00

lpiglet1

-.0143524

-1.15

0.252

0.34902000E+00

0.53851269E+01

lcapital

.0112441

0.49

0.622

-0.16002423E-01

-0.11912307E+01

lfamily

.0048566

0.20

0.841

-0.58796128E-02

-0.23016912E+00

lfeedc

-.235054

-6.08

0.000

0.22821470E-01

0.77516667E+00

contrac1

-.6002783

-0.97

0.330

-0.24699749E+00

-0.52048989E+01

guarante

-.0153806

-0.20

0.845

-0.69546269E+00

-0.11900740E+01

baby

.4116233

3.53

0.000

-0.60600705E-01

-0.69288685E+00

fcircle

-.066693

-0.74

0.456

0.42600132E+00

0.34815182E+01

_cons

8.244913

7.40

0.000

-0.76260601E-01

-0.83231565E+00

mu

lagehh

9.734581

2.41

0.016

-0.53726676E+01

-0.22347456E+01

lyearedu

2.038238

1.32

0.187

0.15271970E+01

0.24004691E+01

lexperhh

-1.821086

-1.28

0.199

0.33716259E+00

0.14827647E+01

female

1.108784

0.94

0.346

-0.24688461E+00

-0.13111818E+01

training

-5.890432

-2.17

0.030

0.32313392E+00

0.11705213E+01

manage

-4.266829

-1.91

0.056

-0.13215068E+01

-0.34826256E+01

lvillkm

-1.305942

-2.04

0.041

-0.95415413E+00

-0.25632361E+01

ldenfarm

1.005259

1.01

0.311

-0.26329598E+00

-0.37419329E+01

lslaugkm

-.4734774

-1.07

0.283

-0.11971431E+00

-0.14307542E+01

ventil

-5.594481

-1.53

0.127

-0.89805088E-01

-0.11732542E+01

changfed

.5236375

0.42

0.673

-0.54721867E+00

-0.10979327E+01

service

-2.411771

-1.60

0.109

-0.90488761E-01

-0.26903185E+00

tranpro

-3.733274

-1.45

0.146

-0.17878494E+00

-0.55834395E+00

credit

-2.370204

-1.88

0.060

-0.16364566E+00

-0.16668469E+00

creconst

1.822142

0.42

0.677

-0.40004809E+00

-0.14528384E+01

east

3.669295

1.49

0.136

-0.44029292E+00

-0.48939463E+00

central

2.81019

1.17

0.243

0.41148370E+00

0.67682746E+00

pre_envm2

.001631

2.22

0.026

-0.26642222E-01

-0.42728765E-01

_cons

-42.46915

-2.28

0.023

0.43776833E-03

0.29880210E+01

/lnsigma2

-.7477716

-2.97

0.003

0.28550959E+00

0.47002522E+01

/ilgtgamma

1.62068

4.58

0.000

0.74584312E+00

0.10722548E+02

sigma2

.4734204





gamma

.8348888





sigma_u2

.3952534





sigma_v2

.078167





Table 8.7 Profit Frontier Estimates With Two Feed Prices

Model 3

Stoc. frontier normal/truncated-normal model

Number of obs = 171


Wald chi2(12) = 364.26

Log likelihood = -39.653183

Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

ladjprof

STATA OUPTPUT

FRONTIER OUTPUT

Coef.

z

P>|z|

Coeff

t-ratio

ladjprof

lmixp

-.0062875

-0.10

0.917

0.83931503E+01

0.76788210E+01

lredp

.0242171

0.24

0.808

-0.61746178E-02

-0.10190774E+00

lwage2

-.0474026

-0.51

0.608

-0.24131747E-01

-0.28237884E+00

lpricpig

.3308998

5.26

0.000

-0.81512428E-01

-0.76067525E+00

lpiglet1

-.0130516

-1.04

0.297

0.34128395E+00

0.51258031E+01

lcapital

.0128857

0.54

0.590

-0.14341449E-01

-0.10672161E+01

lfamily

.0096757

0.38

0.704

-0.29536262E-02

-0.11737183E+00

lfeedc

-.2269469

-5.89

0.000

0.23729899E-01

0.81157802E+00

contrac1

.0809832

0.07

0.944

-0.23812577E+00

-0.52445772E+01

guarante

-.0171834

-0.21

0.837

-0.37283563E+00

-0.43874935E+00

baby

.3845326

3.27

0.001

-0.90396315E-01

-0.10071102E+01

fcircle

-.0707697

-0.79

0.432

0.39018783E+00

0.32358319E+01

_cons

7.512341

5.37

0.000

-0.88951393E-01

-0.98380154E+00

mu

lagehh

9.825092

2.30

0.021

-0.58218079E+01

-0.23412573E+01

lyearedu

2.056941

1.30

0.192

0.15813859E+01

0.25142848E+01

lexperhh

-1.818444

-1.19

0.234

0.35287397E+00

0.15479525E+01

female

1.089224

0.91

0.362

-0.20998300E+00

-0.10439538E+01

training

-5.893629

-2.05

0.041

0.28310399E+00

0.89303053E+00

manage

-4.344821

-1.81

0.070

-0.13540768E+01

-0.36093588E+01

lvillkm

-1.32589

-1.94

0.052

-0.10290059E+01

-0.27683106E+01

ldenfarm

1.021471

0.97

0.330

-0.27791979E+00

-0.39903910E+01

lslaugkm

-.4691674

-1.01

0.311

-0.11740267E+00

-0.13729998E+01

ventil

-5.464238

-1.41

0.158

-0.91826036E-01

-0.12821268E+01

changfed

.4909505

0.38

0.702

-0.62812349E+00

-0.13371031E+01

service

-2.461398

-1.56

0.118

-0.49632440E-01

-0.14557048E+00

tranpro

-3.761768

-1.39

0.164

-0.86739171E-01

-0.25495720E+00

credit

-2.418046

-1.80

0.071

-0.81576402E-01

-0.81631566E-01

creconst

2.063048

0.51

0.608

-0.39280654E+00

-0.13397778E+01

east

3.726004

1.49

0.137

-0.12988083E+00

-0.14612870E+00

central

2.849473

1.15

0.250

0.44036652E+00

0.82475482E+00

pre_envm2

.0016588

2.10

0.036

0.58513543E-01

0.98894821E-01

_cons

-42.95938

-2.22

0.027

0.42285513E-03

0.29979869E+01

/lnsigma2

-.7444701

-2.55

0.011

0.32125923E+00

0.55064139E+01

/ilgtgamma

1.630815

4.05

0.000

0.77349977E+00

0.13493418E+02

sigma2

.4749859





gamma

.8362813





sigma_u2

.3972218





sigma_v2

.0777641





Table 8.8 Profit Frontier Estimates With Positive Feed Price and Interaction Terms

Model 5

Stoc. frontier normal/truncated-normal model

Number of obs = 171


Wald chi2(14) = 386.20

Log likelihood = -37.362518

Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

ladjprof

STATA OUPTPUT

FRONTIER OUTPUT

Coef.

z

P>|z|

Coeff

t-ratio

ladjprof

lfeedp1

-.0435266

-0.62

0.535

0.87373150E+01

0.82558095E+01

lwage2

-.0407285

-0.45

0.651

-0.33903176E-01

-0.44799871E+00

lpricpig

.3641786

5.75

0.000

-0.12215805E+00

-0.13766199E+01

lpiglet1

-.0188967

-1.49

0.137

0.35139912E+00

0.50080168E+01

lcapital

.0137281

0.61

0.540

-0.22979746E-01

-0.14974365E+01

lfamily

.0105896

0.44

0.663

-0.54798890E-02

-0.21186258E+00

lfeedc

-.2436628

-6.31

0.000

0.27105914E-01

0.79320440E+00

contrac1

.104946

0.07

0.947

-0.26094986E+00

-0.40770534E+01

guarante

-6.304572

-1.69

0.092

0.24975229E+00

0.24326350E+00

baby

.2878259

2.25

0.025

-0.71102285E+01

-0.69078558E+01

fcircle

-.1291851

-1.38

0.168

0.31403360E+00

0.21825578E+01

confed

-.0124583

-0.07

0.941

-0.16382811E+00

-0.17599922E+01

guafed

.1142236

0.44

0.661

-0.30831110E-01

-0.27680717E+00

guapri

.4892566

1.87

0.062

0.10174289E+00

0.42362484E+00

_cons

7.731771

6.82

0.000

0.57066677E+00

0.26987130E+01

mu

lagehh

8.731585

2.64

0.008

-0.53412207E+01

-0.23608579E+01

lyearedu

1.761676

1.33

0.182

0.15614646E+01

0.23984878E+01

lexperhh

-1.763027

-1.39

0.166

0.30841929E+00

0.13741379E+01

female

.9892071

0.92

0.360

-0.31842031E+00

-0.12114354E+01

training

-5.184308

-2.35

0.019

0.14481074E+00

0.40994519E+00

manage

-4.154857

-2.09

0.036

-0.13408487E+01

-0.34533346E+01

lvillkm

-1.234664

-2.13

0.034

-0.99209357E+00

-0.21588138E+01

ldenfarm

.9516501

1.07

0.284

-0.27792740E+00

-0.37214313E+01

lslaugkm

-.4611647

-1.17

0.241

-0.14351986E+00

-0.11085066E+01

ventil

-5.412988

-1.69

0.091

-0.87585858E-01

-0.91504982E+00

changfed

.3807105

0.33

0.742

-0.51855013E+00

-0.86822457E+00

service

-2.112299

-1.66

0.098

-0.17283256E+00

-0.41810616E+00

tranpro

-3.341384

-1.51

0.132

-0.87009549E-01

-0.13009265E+00

credit

-2.191018

-1.95

0.052

-0.82957596E-01

-0.81875789E-01

creconst

1.456743

0.29

0.769

-0.34566059E+00

-0.13114741E+01

east

3.117448

1.55

0.120

0.59081056E-01

0.64788389E-01

central

2.407789

1.15

0.249

0.64100130E+00

0.11363962E+01

pre_envm2

.0015348

2.35

0.019

0.21799432E+00

0.35941957E+00

_cons

-37.54492

-2.52

0.012

0.44971578E-03

0.29544289E+01

/lnsigma2

-.8816336

-5.01

0.000

0.28080370E+00

0.54979219E+01

/ilgtgamma

1.486239

5.41

0.000

0.74386893E+00

0.11750054E+02

sigma2

.4141059





gamma

.815513





sigma_u2

.3377088





sigma_v2

.0763971





Table 8.9 Technical Efficiency by Farm Size: Pooled Sample


Farm size

Total

1-100

101-500

501-1000

>1000

Pooled Farms

Model 1: Stata

0.8261

0.8972

0.9084

0.9478

0.9047

Model 2: Frontier

0.7495

0.8266

0.8541

0.8952

0.8418

Model 3: Stata

0.8257

0.8960

0.9078

0.9476

0.9040

Model 4: Frontier

0.7511

0.8216

0.8431

0.8835

0.8345

Model 5: Stata

0.8237

0.9021

0.9116

0.9501

0.9078

Model 6: Frontier

0.7603

0.8314

0.8519

0.8944

0.8443

Model 7: Stata

0.8226

0.9003

0.9100

0.9489

0.9062

Model 8: Frontier

-

-

-

-

-

Piglet farms

Model 1: Stata

0.6038

0.6761

0.6184

0.6117

0.6542

Model 2: Frontier

0.8394

0.8682

0.8316

0.9280

0.8622

Model 3: Stata

0.5708

0.6373

0.5762

0.6029

0.6174

Model 4: Frontier

0.8492

0.8706

0.8429

0.9412

0.8676

Model 5: Stata

0.5206

0.5408

0.4637

0.4879

0.5235

Model 6: Frontier

0.8260

0.8513

0.8037

0.9122

0.8442

Model 7: Stata

0.5238

0.5412

0.4618

0.5013

0.5247

Model 8: Frontier

0.7790

0.8209

0.7924

0.8427

0.8123

Fattening farms

Model 1: Stata

-

-

-

-

-

Model 2: Frontier

0.7269

0.7868

0.8286

0.7272

0.7725

Model 3: Stata

-

-

-

-

-

Model 4: Frontier

0.7291

0.7789

0.8208

0.7241

0.7673

Model 5: Stata

-

-

-

-

-

Model 6: Frontier

0.7054

0.7332

0.7093

0.7284

0.7220

Model 7: Stata

-

-

-

-

-

Model 8: Frontier

-

-

-

-

-

Table 8.10 Profit Frontier Estimation of Piglet Farms

Model 1

Stoc. frontier normal/truncated-normal model

Number of obs = 53


Wald chi2(8) = 128.52

Log likelihood = -3.8734135

Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

ladjprof

Coef.

z

P>|z|

ladjprof

lfeedp

.1845952

0.71

0.477

lwage2

.1270742

0.96

0.336

lpricpig

.7458298

2.53

0.012

lcapital

.1102171

2.75

0.006

lfamily

.119224

1.86

0.063

lfeedc

-.9082516

-7.44

0.000

contrac1

1.968981

0.85

0.396

guarante

.3514517

2.31

0.021

_cons

.6669241

0.15

0.883

mu

lagehh

.361713

1.31

0.189

lyearedu

.1690594

1.41

0.159

lexperhh

-.0530126

-0.66

0.511

female

-.0920135

-0.62

0.534

training

-.2939927

-2.71

0.007

manage

-.0323748

-0.26

0.797

lvillkm

-.0330154

-1.14

0.252

ldenfarm

.0735858

1.23

0.218

lslaugkm

.0656236

1.28

0.202

ventil

.1643864

1.38

0.168

changfed

-.2295173

-1.88

0.060

service

.1943116

1.44

0.151

credit

-.1348643

-1.27

0.205

creconst

-.3209293

-2.11

0.035

east

.1055961

0.47

0.642

central

-.9578744

-3.33

0.001

pre_envm2

.0000374

0.76

0.446

_cons

-1.168598

-0.90

0.367

/lnsigma2

-2.686528

-14.90

0.000

/ilgtgamma

-5.598751

-0.66

0.512

sigma2

.068117



gamma

.0036888



sigma_u2

.0002513



sigma_v2

.0678657



technical efficiency

size

mean

sd

variance

small 1-100

.6038311

.1039406

.0108036

medium low 101-500

.676099

.2362404

.0558095

medium high 501-1000

.6184104

.1517437

.0230262

large > 1000

.6116687

.125481

.0157455

Total

.6541994

.2059331

.0424084

Table 8.11 Profit Frontier Estimation of the Fattening Farms

Output from the program FRONTIER (Version 4.1c)


coefficient

standard-error

t-ratio


beta 0

0.13382054E+02

0.99794208E+00

0.13409650E+02

_cons

beta 1

-0.63433960E+00

0.79830337E+00

-0.79460970E+00

lfeedp1

beta 2

-0.38468273E+00

0.83384842E+00

-0.46133412E+00

lwage2

beta 3

0.61495459E+00

0.73398982E+00

0.83782442E+00

lpricpig

beta 4

-0.92899865E-01

0.98150134E-01

-0.94650777E+00

lpiglet1

beta 5

-0.12745242E+00

0.15788755E+00

-0.80723540E+00

lcapital

beta 6

0.41440725E-01

0.24901626E+00

0.16641775E+00

lfamily

beta 7

0.62097592E-02

0.48685705E+00

0.12754790E-01

lfeedc

beta 8

-0.39053052E+00

0.99452427E+00

-0.39268073E+00

contrac1

beta 9

-0.55999977E+02

0.99535558E+00

-0.56261278E+02

guarante

beta10

-0.29271233E+00

0.97066312E+00

-0.30155913E+00

fcircle

beta11

0.29458090E+00

0.27213670E+00

0.10824740E+01

confed

beta12

0.99577810E-01

0.11553938E+00

0.86185170E+00

guafed

beta13

0.54546971E+01

0.52065843E-02

0.10476537E+04

guapri

delta 0

-0.58352073E+00

0.98229165E+00

-0.59404021E+00

_cons

delta 1

-0.21829149E+01

0.39779907E+00

-0.54874812E+01

lagehh

delta 2

-0.12234699E+01

0.92567604E+00

-0.13217042E+01

lyearedu

delta 3

-0.14962041E+01

0.83021273E+00

-0.18021936E+01

lexperhh

delta 4

-0.44909854E-01

0.99738501E+00

-0.45027600E-01

female

delta 5

-0.47457256E-01

0.94084919E+00

-0.50440874E-01

training

delta 6

0.24849884E+00

0.82827642E+00

0.30001921E+00

manage

delta 7

0.48462693E+00

0.18406585E+00

0.26328998E+01

lvillkm

delta 8

-0.66450334E+00

0.51371567E+00

-0.12935236E+01

ldenfarm

delta 9

-0.72151501E+00

0.69401940E+00

-0.10396179E+01

lslaugkm

delta10

-0.29977748E+00

0.93250489E+00

-0.32147551E+00

ventil

delta11

-0.23526913E+00

0.82735253E+00

-0.28436382E+00

changfed

delta12

0.41573020E+00

0.41204406E-01

0.10089460E+02

service

delta13

-0.22212404E-01

0.99982566E+00

-0.22216277E-01

tranpro

delta14

-0.22992696E+00

0.76317416E+00

-0.30127718E+00

credit

delta15

-0.21486599E-01

0.94596529E+00

-0.22713940E-01

creconst

delta16

-0.27376367E+00

0.87745294E+00

-0.31199812E+00

east

delta17

-0.12062621E-01

0.64851673E+00

-0.18600323E-01

central

delta18

0.32134908E-02

0.14256293E-02

0.22540857E+01

pre_envm2

sigma-squared

0.10123593E+02

0.36997313E+01

0.27363049E+01


gamma

0.83677597E+00

0.40332387E-01

0.20746999E+02


log likelihood function = -0.14700435E+03

LR test of the one-sided error = 0.22189091E+03

with number of restrictions = *

[note that this statistic has a mixed chi-square distribution]

number of iterations = 33

(maximum number of iterations set at: 100)

number of cross-sections = 90

number of time periods = 1

total number of observations = 90

technical efficiency

size

mean

sd

variance

small 1-100

0.705449008

0.042578843

0.001812958

medium low 101-500

0.733213069

0.043772759

0.001916054

medium high 501-1000

0.70933616

0.052037639

0.002707916

large >1000

0.728427341

0.055375537

0.00306645

Total

0.721953631

0.050423389

0.002542518


[113] Another method is to estimate a hedonic wage function from the farms that employ hired labor. Then, the wages of the family workers con be predicted from the hedonic function on the basis of the characteristics of the farms.

Previous Page Top of Page Next Page