Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


A Special Agricultural Safeguard (SAS): buttressing the market access reforms of developing countries[31]


Comments by Mr Dale E. Hathaway

Agricultural markets are by nature cyclical and subject to wide fluctuations due, among other things, to weather variability. The subsidizing of agricultural production and exports, as well as the anti-competitive behaviour of trading firms (both state-owned and private), also affect the orderly development and flow of trade. As countries reduce tariffs and bind them at low levels, they become increasingly vulnerable to external agricultural market instability and to import surges that could wipe out viable, well-established or nascent, agricultural production activities. Vulnerability to such external shocks is of particular concern to developing countries that are endeavouring to develop their agricultural potential and diversify production in order to enhance their food security and alleviate poverty.

There are numerous instances of the implementation of reduction commitments by developing countries being associated with more frequent import surges which have damaged or threaten to damage or displace viable domestic production.[32] To cope with this situation, some countries have reacted, where applied tariffs are below bound levels, by varying (raising) duties within the limits of their bound levels or imposing or varying other charges.[33] However, as bound rates are brought down, the scope for such action is correspondingly reduced. Indeed, because of the real risk of import surges, many countries that do not have access to an effective safeguard instrument are reluctant to reduce further their bound tariffs, in particular below levels which would impede them from varying applied tariffs as an effective safeguard instrument.

Within WTO there are two safeguard instruments - Article XIX of GATT 1994 (and its elaboration in the Uruguay Round Agreement on Safeguards) and the special safeguard (SSG) provisions under the Agreement on Agriculture (Article 5). Both instruments were designed to address the problem of sudden increases in imports that cause or threaten to cause serious injury to viable domestic producers.[34] The first of these two instruments is concerned with the possibility of a surge in imports following tariff cuts. In such cases, in order to allow domestic producers time to adjust gradually to the increased competition, the importing country may revoke the tariff concession in whole or in part for temporary periods if, after investigations carried out by competent authorities, it is established that the increase in imports is such as to cause serious injury to domestic producers of like or directly competitive products. Such measures should be applied on an MFN basis to imports from all sources for a maximum period of 8 years for a particular product (10 years in the case of developing countries).

The country proposing to revoke its tariff concessions under these provisions is expected to offer trade compensation to countries whose trade interests would be adversely affected. If agreement on adequate compensation cannot be reached, the affected countries may take retaliatory action, normally in the form of suspension of a concession or other obligation to which the country applying the safeguard measure is entitled. Overall, while Article XIX and the Agreement on Safeguards allow safeguard action against a surge of imports threatening domestic producers, in practice there are limitations in resorting to these provisions. Few developing countries have the resources and the institutional and legal capacity to apply such measures which, in addition, require proof of injury and involve a lengthy and costly legal process. Simplifications and improvements in these provisions are necessary if they are to become an effective safeguard instrument for developing countries.

Another possibility could be to improve the present SSG provisions, which are designed to deal with the specific nature and problems of the agricultural sector. Because of the negotiating history of the Uruguay Round, the provisions were agreed to in conjunction with tariffication as a package, and recourse to SSG was limited to those countries undertaking tariffication. However, in the current tariffs-only trade environment faced by all WTO members, there is now the anomaly that some (see annexes I-III) have the right to use the agricultural safeguard to deal with import surges, whereas others, including many vulnerable developing members, do not. The right to make use of the SSG provision has been reserved by 36 WTO Members, and for a limited number of products in each case. As many of the developing countries did not tariffy, offering “ceiling bindings” instead, few of them have access to this provision. Moreover, there are also issues involved in the modalities of its application.

At present there are two types of contingencies for which safeguard action is authorized: a surge in the volume of imports or a sharp fall in import prices. Corresponding quantity and price triggers are defined as well as the amount of additional duties that may be levied above the bound ceiling level.

Under the volume-based SSG, the trigger volume is derived from: i) actual imports averaged over the preceding three years; ii) the share of imports in domestic consumption over the same period; and iii) the absolute volume change in consumption over the most recent year for which data are available (see Box 1). The trigger level is higher (and the probability of using the trigger less), the greater the three-year average level of imports, the lower the share of imports in domestic consumption, and the faster the growth in domestic consumption. The maximum extra duty may not exceed 30 percent of the ordinary level of duty in effect during the year in which the SSG is invoked; it may not be levied beyond the end of the year in which it has been imposed; and it cannot be applied to imports taking place within tariff quotas.

Box 1. Special Agricultural Safeguard: Quantitative Trigger Levels

In accordance with Article 5, paragraph 4, of the AoA, an additional duty may be imposed in any year where the absolute volume of imports (M) exceeds the sum of the base trigger level (x) multiplied by the average quantity of imports during the three preceding years for which data are available () and the absolute volume change in domestic consumption of the product concerned in the most recent year for which data are available compared to the preceding year (y). In algebraic terms this is expressed as:

where, Mt is the trigger level of imports and x (the base trigger level) is defined according to the following schedule based on the share of imports in domestic consumption during the three preceding years (S). Thus:


=

125 %,

if S £ 10 %

x

=

110 %,

if 10 % < S £ 30 %


=

105 %,

if S > 30 %


For example, if the share of imports in domestic consumption during the preceding three years is 7 percent, then x will be equal to 1.25. Thus an additional duty can be imposed if current imports (M) exceed the trigger volume (Mt), i.e.

The maximum extra duty shall not exceed 30 percent of the level of the ordinary customs duty in effect in the year in which the action is taken, it shall only be maintained to the end of the year in which it has been imposed and cannot be applied to imports taking place within tariff quotas.

Box 2. Special Agricultural Safeguard: Price Trigger Levels

Let:



PM = current c.i.f. import price of the shipment (expressed in domestic currency)

PT = trigger price (average c.i.f. price for 1986-88)

D = (PT - PM)/PT (the percentage fall in the import price below the trigger price).


In accordance with Article 5, paragraph 5, of the AoA, an additional duty, expressed in ad valorem equivalent (t), may be imposed according to the following schedule:

If:





(a) D £ 10%

then t = 0

(b) 10% < D £ 40%

then t = 0.27 (PT/PM) - 0.3

(c) 40% < D £ 60%

then t = 0.39 (PT/PM) - 0.5

(d) 60% < D £ 75%

then t = 0.47 (PT/PM) - 0.7

(e) D > 75%

then t = 0.52 (PT/PM) - 0.9


Example: Assume a trigger price of US$120 per unit and that the current c.i.f. import price is US$60. Since the import price is 50 percent of the trigger price, case (c) applies. Consequently, an additional duty equivalent to 28 percent of the c.i.f. import price could be levied, which would bring the price of the imported product to US$76.8.

The additional duty can only be imposed on the shipment concerned and cannot be applied to imports taking place within tariff quotas.


Under the price-based SSG the trigger price is defined as the average c.i.f. unit value during the 1986-88 base period, expressed in domestic currency. The permitted level of the additional duty depends upon the degree to which the import price falls below this trigger level (see Box 2 and Figures 1 and 2). The greater the decline in the import price below the trigger level, the higher is the duty. However, the additional duty does not completely offset the fall in the import price.[35]

Graphical illustration of the price-based safeguard (SSG)


Figure 1: Additional duty under price-based SSG

Figure 2: Effect on import price of additional price-based SSG, assuming a trigger price of US$ 120

While resort to these provisions has not been widespread so far, the SSG is considered an important safeguard instrument in the agricultural sector in view of the automatic nature of its application. Clearly, one of the reasons for the creation of this sector-specific instrument was the recognition that the general safeguard provision of GATT 1994 did not offer the degree of assurance that countries desired in order to move into a tariff-only regime and to reduce those tariffs over time.

However, the future of the SSG provision, which was intended to remain in force for the duration of the reform process as determined in Article 20 of the AoA, is uncertain. In the context of the continuation of this reform process, some WTO members have called for its elimination, while others have suggested various options for its continuation in a modified form, including the possibility of extending it to all countries (developing and developed) and to all agricultural commodities.[36] However, the implications of such a general application of safeguards need to be carefully considered.[37]

In the consideration of how the SSG might be extended, it is important to bear in mind its original purpose, which was to allow countries to raise their applied tariffs above the bound ceilings in cases where, even if the ceiling was applied, domestic producers would face difficulties. Such difficulties are more likely to arise for commodities with relatively low bound tariffs and than for those where they are relatively high. Consequently, an extended SSG-type instrument might need to be limited in respect of both the breadth of its coverage (commodity eligibility) and its depth (extent of additional duties allowed).

Elements of such a revised Special Agricultural Safeguard (SAS) could include the following:

Both of these criteria aim at confining the application of safeguard measures to dealing with the problem they were intended to address, i.e. protect domestic producers from import surges and the threat of very low prices originating from the world market, when protection from existing border and/or domestic support measures is limited.

Annex I - WTO Members eligible to use the Special Agricultural Safeguard

Member

Year of tariff data

Percentage of agricultural
tariff lines covered by SSG*

Developed countries

Australia

1988

2

Bulgaria

n.a.

n.a.

Canada

1988

10

Czech Republic

1990

13

EC (12)

1988

31

Hungary

1991

60

Iceland

1988

40

Israel

n.a.

n.a.

Japan

1988

12

New Zealand

1991

n.a.

Norway

1988

49

Poland

1989

66

Romania

1991

7

Slovak Republic

1990

13

Switzerland-Liechtenstein

1988

59

United States

1989

9

Developing countries

Barbados

n.a.

n.a.

Botswana**

n.a.

n.a.

Colombia

1991

27

Costa Rica***

1988

13

Ecuador

n.a.

n.a.

El Salvador***

1989

10

Guatemala

n.a.

n.a.

Indonesia

1989

1

Korea, Rep. of

1988

8

Malaysia

1988

5

Mexico

1988

29

Morocco

n.a.

n.a.

Namibia**

1988

39

Nicaragua

n.a.

n.a.

Panama

n.a.

n.a.

Philippines

1991

13

South Africa**

1988

39

Swaziland**

1988

39

Thailand

1988

11

Tunisia

1989

4

Venezuela

1990

31

* Number of agricultural tariff lines covered by the SSG as a proportion of the number of all agricultural tariff lines.

** Member of the Southern African Customs Union (SACU).

*** Customs Cooperation Council Nomenclature (CCCN).

n.a. = not available.

Source: WTO document G/AG/NG/S/9, 6 June 2000, Table 1.

Annex II - Potential Application of the Special Agricultural Safeguard - Number of tariff items and product groups involved

WTO Member

Number of tariff items

Number of product groups
(HS 4-digit headings)

Developed countries

Australia

10

2

Bulgaria

21

9

Canada

150

37

Czech Republic

236

29

Ecuador

7

1

EC (15)

539

72

Hungary

117

117

Iceland

462

121

Israel

41

14

Japan

121

27

New Zealand

4

2

Norway

581

141

Poland

144

133

Romania

175

14

Slovak Republic

114

28

Switzerland-Liechtenstein

961

134

United States

189

26

Sub-total

4 149

1 016

Developing countries

Barbados

37

24

Botswana

161

71

Colombia

56

55

Costa Rica

87

24

El Salvador

84

23

Guatemala

107

35

Indonesia

13

4

Korea, Rep. of

111

34

Malaysia

72

12

Mexico

293

83

Morocco

374

46

Namibia

166

75

Nicaragua

21

14

Panama

6

2

Philippines

118

36

South Africa

166

75

Swaziland

166

75

Thailand

52

23

Tunisia

32

13

Uruguay

2

1

Venezuela

76

63

Sub-total

1 923

679

Total

6 072

1 695

Note: Since Schedules differ in the level of tariff disaggregation, figures in the first column of this table cannot be readily compared among Members. In many cases the right to recourse to the SSG is limited to only part of the HS (Harmonized System) 4-digit heading concerned.

Source: WTO document G/AG/NG/S/9, 6 June 2000, Table 2.

Annex III - Potential application of the Special Agricultural Safeguard - Number of tariff items involved in each product category

WTO
member

Product category *

CE

OI

SG

DA

ME

EG

BV

FV

TO

FI

CO

OA

ALL

Developed countries

Australia

-

-

-

5

-

-

-

-

5

-

-

-

10

Bulgaria

-

-

-

8

4

-

1

-

7

-

1

-

21

Canada

51

2

-

34

43

6

1

-

-

-

7

6

150

Czech Rep.

10

20

7

35

95

-

57

6

-

-

3

3

236

EC (15)

76

11

28

110

192

8

12

45

-

-

4

53

539

Hungary

15

6

3

6

18

2

9

37

3

-

13

5

117

Iceland

63

92

37

24

92

5

2

79

-

-

19

49

462

Israel

1

1

-

1

31

-

1

5

-

-

-

1

41

Japan

41

2

-

29

32

-

0

6

-

2

8

1

121

New Zealand

-

-

-

-

-

-

0

2

-

-

-

2

4

Norway

81

93

22

24

84

6

8

168

-

-

34

61

581

Poland

15

13

4

6

19

2

10

38

3

3

9

22

144

Romania

9

-

-

48

62

-

51

1

1

-

3

-

175

Slovak Rep.

10

8

2

7

70

-

7

6

-

-

1

3

114

Switzerland/














Liechtenstein

263

138

25

48

94

5

35

219

-

-

49

85

961

United States

15

3

16

73

12

-

1

3

-

6

58

2

189

Sub-total

732

409

148

464

891

31

214

656

22

11

168

94

4 142

Developing countries

Barbados

1

1**

1

2

5

1

5

21

-

-

-

-

37

Botswana

37

16

4

6

37

2

19

29

3

-

-

4

161

Colombia

10

24

3

5

6

-

1

1

-

1

-

5

56

Costa Rica

7

3

4

26

32

7

-

1

6

-

1

-

87

Ecuador

-

-

-

7

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

7

El Salvador

6

27

15

15

12

-

-

-

9

-

-

-

84

Guatemala

16

16

4

21

22

2

7

10

9

-

-

-

107

Indonesia

-

-

-

12

-

-

-

-

-

-

1

-

13

Korea, Rep of

42

2

-

-

6

1

-

12

-

-

2

46

111

Malaysia

1

-

10

4

38

12

-

1

5

-

1

-

72

Mexico

44

32

24

37

54

9

44

11

10

-

26

2

293

Morocco

98

98

56

77

45

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

374

Namibia

40

18

4

6

37

2

19

29

3

-

4

4

166

Nicaragua

7

3

1

3

6

-

-

1

-

-

-

-

21

Panama

-

-

-

6

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

6

Philippines

14

-

2

-

86

-

-

7

-

-

7

2

118

South Africa

40

18

4

6

37

2

19

29

3

-

4

4

166

Swaziland

40

18

4

6

37

2

19

29

3

-

4

4

166

Thailand

4

12

4

4

-

-

1

9

3

1

13

1

52

Tunisia

2

-

4

8

14

-

-

4

-

-

-

-

32

Uruguay

2

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

2

Venezuela

26

29

3

6

5

-

-

-

-

-

1

6

76

Sub-total

355

296

143

251

356

37

115

153

51

2

58

28

1 930

All Members

1 087

706

291

715

1 327

74

329

809

73

13

277

371

6 072

* For the definition of the product categories and the codes used, see the appendix to this annex.

** Whole of Chapter 15.

Source: WTO document G/AG/NG/S/9, 6 June 2000, Table 3.

Appendix to Annex III - Definition of product categories

Code Product category

Harmonized System nomenclature

CE

Cereals

1001-08, 1101-04, 1107-09, 1901-05,

OI

Oil seeds, fats and oils and products

1201-08, Ch.15 (except 1504), 2304-06

SG

Sugar and confectionery

1701-04

DA

Dairy products

0401-06

ME

Animals and products thereof

0101-06, 0201-10,1601-02

EG

Eggs

0407-08

BV

Beverages and spirits

2009, 2201-08

FV

Fruit and vegetables

0701-14, 0801-14, 1105-06, 2001-08

TO

Tobacco

2401-03

FI

Agricultural fibres

5001-03, 5101-03, 5201-03, 5301-02

CO

Coffee, tea, mate, cocoa and preparations; Spices and other food preparations

0409-10, 0901-10, 1801, 1803-06, 2101-06, 2209

OA

Other agricultural products

Ch.05 (except 0509), 0601-04, 1209-10, 1211-14, 1301-02, 1401-04, 1802, 2301 (except 2301.20), 2302-03, 2307-09, 2905.43-44, 3301, 3501-05, 3809.10, 3823.60, 4101-03, 4301,

Comments by Mr Dale E. Hathaway

Director
National Center for Food and Agricultural Policy
Washington, D.C.

Rationale is compelling - If you expect to negotiate deep cuts in agricultural tariffs countries must have some way of protecting exposed agricultural industries to import surges or to disastrously low import prices that could permanently damage or eliminate a viable competitive sector. This is a special problem for developing countries that lack fiscal resources to compensate producers.

Dangers - There is a tendency to devise policy measures that are as bad as the problems they cure. TRQs are a prime example. Therefore, one should make certain that the system devised does not end up as a new protectionist device.

Some political realities- Developed countries will not give up their SSGs unless they have access to the newly-devised safeguard for agriculture. Therefore the latter needs to be considered for all products in all countries, with special rules for developing countries regarding some aspect of their use.

Some general principles - Keep the agricultural safeguard simple and easy to use, but set up criteria to limit its use to situations of import surges or very low import prices and to products that have bound tariffs below a specified level. Develop a phase-down period, so that protection gradually returns to the original level. This period could be longer for developing countries. Triggers should be defined and known in advance.


[31] Paper prepared by the FAO Commodities and Trade Division for the FAO Round Table on Selected Agricultural Trade Policy Issues, Geneva, 21 March 2001.
[32] Three examples are Jamaica, with respect to chicken, Kenya with respect to dairy products, and Senegal with respect to tomato paste (see FAO (2000), Agriculture, Trade and Food Security: Issues and Options in the WTO Negotiations from the Perspective of Developing Countries, Vol. II - Country Case Studies. Rome). Other examples include Chile, Morocco and Peru.
[33] For example, a price-band policy has been used in Peru, a threshold-price-based formula for determining import tariffs in Morocco, suspended duties (surcharges) in Kenya and additional stamp duties in Jamaica (ibid).
[34] Contingency measures are also provided for in other WTO Agreements - e.g. to deal with injuries resulting from i) dumping by foreign enterprises (GATT Article VI and the Ministerial Decision on the review of Article 17.6 of the Agreement on implementation of that Article); and ii) governmental subsidies (GATT Articles VI and XVI and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures).
[35] As shown in Figures 1 and 2, the additional duty that can be imposed under the price-based SSG would respectively be 3.8 percent, 34 percent and 298 percent where the import price falls below the trigger price by 20 percent, 50 percent and 80 percent. Levying the additional duty in each of these cases would offset only part of the fall in the import price: assuming a trigger price of US$120, the additional duty would raise the import price to only US$99.6, US$80.4 and US$95.4, respectively.
[36] Some suggest eligibility only for developing countries and others for developing countries where many subsistence producers are involved. Yet others suggest applicability of an SSG-type measure to a smaller set of “sensitive” agricultural commodities, designated by the countries themselves (and applicable to either all countries or developing countries only). Another approach suggests flexibility for countries to raise their applied tariffs above the bound rate in certain circumstances (e.g. extremely low world prices and/or import surges) as long as the average over a period of time remains at or below the bound rate.
[37] This is particularly so if price trigger levels are set too high and resort to the SSG is too frequent. To avoid excessive interference with the world market, the trigger price should be set at a level that is unmistakably low, aimed at protection from extremely low prices that threaten to cause injury to domestic producers. In addition, there is a need for periodic adjustments of the trigger level to reflect possible long-term trends in commodity prices and allow a reasonable degree of transmission of world price changes to the domestic market.
[38] A possible additional requirement could be that the bound ceiling plus the additional tariff should not exceed an absolute overall maximum, which could be uniform for all commodities/countries.
[39] As noted above, compared to developed countries, developing countries have limited resources to make transfers to farmers when world market prices are low, and hence border measures are the main instrument for ensuring domestic price stability.

Previous Page Top of Page Next Page